It was a Saturday morning 55 years ago. A
handful of skippers were sitting in the lobby of the fish salesman’s
office, waiting their turn to ‘settle up’ for the week. Over the
previous 30 years the fish salesmen had acquired enormous power and
authority over the fishing fleets in each port. In addition to selling
the fish, for which they received a modest commission, they also
received the cheques or drafts from the fish buyers and from that
income, paid all of the bills the boats incurred, for fuel, ice, stores,
spare parts and harbour dues. Most of them became the fishermen’s
business office, and kept all of the boats accounts. They also assisted
the fishers with their income tax returns and made all the financial
arrangements for any skipper who wanted to purchase a replacement
vessel. The salesman’s office usually incorporated a ship chandler’s
store, and sold the fishers what ever gear they needed, - nets, ropes,
twine, floats, oilskin smocks, seamen’s boots, knives, and charts. Some
salesmen companies expanded and set up offices in different ports. Among
the big ones on our coast were Cosalt, Salvesen’s, Irvin’s, Duthie’s,
and Caley. Each of them ended up having shares in most of the boats they
served. One fish salesman came to the port as a penniless clerk, and
rose to own a large fish selling company, and to own part of half the
boats in the fleet.
On this particular day, the crew of a local
boat were sitting in a corner with glum expressions on their faces. They
had struggled that year to produce fish and make money, having faced a
series of setbacks with mechanical breakdowns and poor markets. Their
boat was aging and a bit small for fishing offshore. It is like that
sometimes in the fishing. When things are going well it seems you cannot
put a foot wrong, and all of your decisions result in success at sea and
on the fish market. But you can run into a seemingly endless period of
difficulty when nothing appears to go right, and you never get to turn
the corner from hard times to days of plenty. So as hard as they had
been working, this skipper and crew were up against it. The fish
salesman had called them in to review the situation. He appeared from
his office carrying a big ledger, and with a bad-tempered countenance
ushered the fishers into a small room as if they were criminals and he
was an interrogator. The crew followed him submissively with bowed heads
and humble expressions, watched by the waiting group of skippers. The
door closed behind them and one of the skippers turned to his
colleagues. He gestured with his thumb at the room where the crew had
gone, and said simply, “chamber of horrors” !
Even the best of fishers can go through a
period of financial difficulty. Fish market slumps are a common cause of
such problems. After the First World War, the formerly insatiable
markets for salt herring in Germany, Poland, and Russia, collapsed.
Those countries were bankrupt, or lacked foreign currency, and were
unable to purchase the fish. The North Sea was still full of herring.
The fleets of steam drifters were still able to bring in boatloads of
the fish. But there were few merchants able to purchase their catches.
For a period the drifters turned to fishing for cod, haddock and plaice
with lines or trawl nets, but those lovely boats that were ideal for
drift netting, were ill-suited to other methods of fishing. They were
also expensive to operate, and coal was rising in price. Soon they were
tied up, sold, or scrapped. A new method of catching white fish was
developed by the Danes. Their snurrevod, or bottom seine, could
be worked by a small boat with a diesel or semi-diesel motor of just 30
to 60 hp. They were soon to become the main producers of plaice in the
North Sea, and after the Scots made the gear more versatile, dispensing
with the anchor used by the Danes, seine net boats could take quality
cod, haddock, hake, and whiting, better than any trawler or line boat of
similar size.
But the transition from drift net to seine,
and from steam to diesel was not made without some financial pain. Some
good skippers that held on their drifters in the hope that the market
would recover, were to lose everything, - boat, savings, and house (for
houses were often mortgaged to finance the family boat). And when the
seine fleet grew to become the dominant fish producer in Scotland, their
catches flooded the market at times, especially in summer when there was
a lot of small fish. As a young apprentice fisherman I have watched
hundreds of boxes of small haddock and whiting go “up the road” to the
fish meal plant. It would have taken crews many sleepless hours to gut
all the fish, but their labour was in vain, and the proceeds from a
rejected catch would not even pay for the fuel and the food. I recall
one skipper, obviously desperate to keep his boat solvent and to give
his crew a wage, pleading with the merchants to buy his catch, even at
the low minimum price. But they were unable to do so. The market was to
stabilise by the 1970’s, and the price paid for a 7 stone box of fish
(98 lbs or 45 kgs) was to rise from £ 2 to £ 5 to £ 10, and later to £
40, and even £ 80 or more by the 1990’s. The herring market was also to
recover, but by then the effective method of capture was purse seine or
midwater trawl which required huge, multi-million pound vessels to
operate.
The last thirty years have seen the
emergence of totally new costs that out forefathers would never have
dreamed possible. Governments have escalated the cost of vessel licenses
by permitting their sale on open markets. On top of the license, the
modern skipper or boat owner has to pay for his fish quota. These have
also become tradable commodities, to the point where today the boat
license and fish quota costs the fishers more than the boat, the engine,
the equipment, the warps, and the fishing gear, together. I sat in the
cabin of a small prawn trawler a few years ago, in the port of Mallaig,
Scotland. Next to a lobster boat, or a prawn creeler, the 40 or 50 foot
prawn trawler is the cheapest fishing unit in my country. The young
skipper was struggling each week to pay all expenses, to give his crew a
living wage, and to pay the loan on the vessel. He explained to me what
he had paid for the fishing unit.
The little second-hand boat he purchased,
together with its electronics, winch, warps and fishing gear, cost him £
30,000. The license he needed to operate vessel, - a mere piece of paper
issued by the government, - cost him £ 90,000. A modest quota
entitlement which authorised him to catch that amount of prawns and
fish, cost a further £ 60,000. So in that simple case, the actual
fishing unit, - the means of production, - was only 17 % of the total
cost paid. The license, - the permission of government to operate the
boat, - was 50 % of the total, and the quota price, - the result of a
government-approved, but iniquitous and immoral trade in fishery access,
was 33 % or a third of the total amount. Therefore, costs imposed by
government on fishing boat operators amount to 88 % of the total
investment. Or to put it another way, - government has imposed
artificial charges on the industry, amounting to as much as 600 % of the
cost of the actual fishing unit and its equipment.
The figures become obscene when we consider
larger fishing units. A 30 metre offshore trawler’s license would be £
500,000 and its fish quota could be £ 1,000,000 or more. For a 60 metre
midwater (pelagic) trawler, the license might be £ 2,000,000 and the
fish quota at least £ 3,000,000. These were the sums that were typical 6
years ago in 2002. I gathered them during a UN FAO assignment to assess
the coastal communities of the Hebrides and West Coast of Scotland. It
was one of five global regions selected by the Kyoto Conference for
examination to obtain examples of the economic, environmental, and
social pressures on fishing communities at the start of the 21st
Century.
Two major items in the operating cost of
fishing boats, that have escalated in recent years, are bank charges and
fuel costs. The excessive costs of licenses and quotas mentioned above,
have obliged many boats to borrow funds. The main loan most vessels
normally carried was for the boat itself. Few fishers could afford to
purchase a boat outright. So it was necessary to borrow for that. In
most cases in my country, the borrower was not a single individual like
the skipper, but also included other crew members, some of whom would be
family members or relatives of the skipper. Happy were the skipper and
crew who were able to pay their capital loan off within ten years.
Interest repayments were highest in the first year and it was vital to
achieve high productivity the first twelve months.
But as economic pressures increased on the
fishing fleets, boat owners began to borrow for other purposes. It might
be a new winch or echo-sounder, or a major refit of the vessel, - but
whatever the purpose, these additional loans, being shorter term,
carried higher interest rates and added significantly to operating
costs. However, the serious additional borrowing began with the
iniquitous quota system that demanded skippers purchase the right to
harvest a certain amount of particular fish species. Those who argued in
favour of the system said that for too long fishers had been able to
fish free of charge, but now they had to pay a ‘rent’ to government for
the right. The problem with that rationale is that the ‘rent’ as
economists like to describe it, is being paid to speculators and banks,
and “slipper skippers”, who have enjoyed the right to catch fish all
their lives; who obtained quota allocations when the cost was initially
low; and who, having retired, make a handsome extra income off the
labours of other less fortunate fishers, by leasing quota rights to
them. (My own view is that if the industry has to pay for a quota
allocation, the payment should go into a special fund to support fish
conservation, and to assist new young entrants to the industry).
These quota borrowings put the banks in a
powerful position which they exploited to the full. In the past, bank
loan interest was paid weekly along with other normal expenses. Now the
banks insisted they be paid first, - before any other expense, and
before any crewman received any remuneration. The resultant pressure
this put on the UK fishing fleets caused a serious drop in crew incomes,
and led some skippers to operate with smaller crews in order to have
more money for the bank repayments. One young fisherman I knew had
worked on good offshore boats, and was making attractive money. But his
skipper then invested in a more powerful vessel which also carried
excessive bank loans for the boat, the license, and the fish quota. He
told me, “We were working very hard, catching plenty fish, and making
good money before. But now we are working much harder, catching more
fish than before, and yet making a lot less money.” Debts mounted on
many similar boats. Local crewmen left the fishing for more stable jobs
on oil rigs or on oil rig service vessels. Their places have mostly been
taken by foreign immigrants. Morale on the boats has declined, and drug
use has escalated. The manager of a leading Fish Salesman’s business in
Peterhead, our top fishing port, pointed to the financial files he held
on scores of vessels, and said, “There are very few boats under our
management which would not be forced to declare bankruptcy if we were to
stop all credit and demand payment of all the debts they owe now.”
Some may contend that business failure
affects all sectors and those who fail should pay the price. My own view
is that the current financial crisis of the fishing industry, like the
housing mortgage crisis, has been created by external forces, and not by
the fishers themselves. Governments have manipulated the allocation of
quotas and licenses to force fishers out of business, (thus avoiding any
obligation to compensate), and this is the result. But they ignore their
responsibility for creating the over-capacity in the first place.
The second major escalating cost item is
fuel. The fishers need diesel fuel to power their creel boats, trawlers,
and seiners. Fuel costs were low for much of the last century for two
reasons. First the actual cost was not excessive, and a fuel subsidy or
tax relief measure was applied for a time. That has changed with the
enormous increases in global oil prices. A second major factor is that
for the last 30 to 40 years there has been a huge increase in the
installed engine power on fishing boats. When I first went to sea, boats
were happily fishing away with motors of 90 hp or 120 hp. A boat with
over 150 hp was considered powerful. Even large deep sea vessels had
engines of only a few hundred horse power. But for certain types of
operation, particularly trawling, more power had the benefit of helping
to catch more fish. Extra speed to get to the fishing grounds and back
to market, was also a motivation. So our fleet structure altered with
greater numbers of larger, more powerful vessels. Boats of 75, 80, and
85 feet in length (22, 24, and 26 metres), were equipped with engines of
500 hp, 750 hp, and even 1,000 hp. Even auxiliary engines to drive
generators and hydraulics, increased from a mere 15 hp, 30 hp, or 50 hp,
up to 120 hp, 150 hp, and even 200 hp. All this added greatly to the
fuel bill, and when fuel prices escalated, the writing was on the wall.
In hindsight it is obvious that there had to
be a sensible limit to the size and power of each boat. Certainly there
are methods of fishing and deep sea conditions that merit a vessel of
substantial size and power. But with stout seaworthy boats, most
countries could harvest their seas comfortably even if he boats are of
modest size and power. Pelagic boats that fish offshore for mackerel and
herring, need to have large capacity, but that apart, I see no need for
the dog-eat-dog rat race to get a power advantage over other boats.
The problem first struck me as a serious
issue, not in the North Sea, but on the shores of Lake Kariba in the
Zambesi valley, where we had mechanised the fishermen with 5 hp
outboards on their 23 foot canoes. The mechanisation worked well. The
fishermen were happy, and catches were increasing. But as I reviewed the
costs and earnings of each fishing unit, it became apparent to me that
most of the extra money generated, was going to pay for the fuel and the
spare parts needed by the outboard motors. The fishermen themselves were
not getting much more money than those whose canoes were un-mechanised.
Later, when in Indonesia, and beginning to
view fisheries issues through the Small is Beautiful philosophy
of Dr E F Schumacher, I began to research different fishing operations
to calculate how much fish were being produced, per ton of fuel used.
Indonesia then had a fleet of over half a million vessels, mostly
sailing canoes, but also many hundreds of long liners, gill net boats,
ring net vessels, pole and line tuna catchers, purse seiners, and shrimp
trawlers. I was able to obtain details of the operations of each. When
in the UK before then I had compiled records of the catches, earnings,
fuel consumption, and specifications of trawlers of varying sizes and
from different ports. To those records I added more data from the Far
East and America, to compile a useful if incomplete chart of the
economic and energy efficiency of each unit. The resulting broad brush
picture indicated that globally, large scale fishing units caught 3.5
tons of fish for each ton of fuel consumed, while the world’s small
scale fleets produced 12.0 tons of fish for each ton of fuel they
burned. Counting only fish for human consumption, the total production
was 29 million tons for large scale sector and 24 million tons for the
small scale fishery sector. The chart also showed that for each million
dollars invested, the large scale fleets employed around 20 persons,
while the small scale fleets gave work to 3,000 fishermen from the same
amount of investment.
The chart caused quite a stir. First
published by ICLARM, the International Centre for Living Aquatic
Resources, (now known as WorldFish), it was the most quoted article by
that organisation in the decade 1980 to 1990. (This information was
compiled following a ten year log of all references to ICLARM material,
by its chief editor). FAO agreed to sponsor its update which I completed
in 1988, and some 18 years later, the World Bank and FAO jointly agreed
to update the study, which they referred to as the Big Numbers Picture,
or the Thomson Table. A copy of the 1988 version is given below.
The ‘big numbers’ study of global fishery
operations was put together in the wake of the first major global energy
crisis of the 20th
century, the OPEC cartel’s control of production to raise oil prices to
unprecedented levels. Seeing the effect it was having on the world’s
fishing fleets, I believed that the study would shed some light on the
situation, and possibly indicate some sensible policies for the future.
Now the world is faced with an even greater escalation of oil prices in
the wake of the War in Iraq, and the grabbing of oil resources by the
USA, China, Russia, and other major consumers. Instead of reducing
consumption and looking for alternative fuels or renewable sources of
energy, most governments are exacerbating the problem by fighting over
the world’s limited and dwindling deposits of petroleum.
In line with my draft of the global
fisheries table, I looked at technological options for the world’s
fishing fleets and fish processing activities. This paper was presented
to the Indo-Pacific fisheries council that met in Kyoto, Japan in 1979.
Today the paper is typical of many thoughtful attempts to develop a more
sustainable fishing industry, but in 1979 there were some in FAO who did
not appear to have realised how the OPEC crisis was impacting on poor
country fisheries. My paper was banned from distribution within the
house. The ban was to continue for 2 years but actually made little
difference. Each time I visited headquarters I was approached by
colleagues who asked if I could provide them with a copy. Perhaps if it
had not been banned, there would have been less interest. The official
who had banned the paper was a died-in-the-wool traditional fisheries
engineer. He objected in principle to my floating of concepts like
construction of artificial reefs, use of waste fish to generate biogas,
and re-adoption of auxiliary sail on long distance fishing boats in the
tropics.
Other officials were much more supportive. I
sought a meeting with the Director of Agriculture and Fisheries in the
Asian Development Bank, headquartered in Manila. Dr Shei graciously
agreed to see me and called his senior staff together to listen to my
proposal. I began by outlining the hardship being caused to poor fishers
by the fuel price increases, and went on to question why, despite that,
both ADB and World Bank were financing loans for fuel-expensive fishing
fleets which would only add to the problem. I suggested that the ADB had
a moral responsibility as a development bank, to make the fishery sector
in the Asia-Pacific region aware of technological alternatives that
would reduce energy and fuel costs. My proposal was for a regional
workshop where fishery sector representatives from all Bank member
countries could come together to discuss and to see practical
demonstrations of appropriate alternative systems suitable to the
region. Dr Shei’s officers each made helpful comments on the idea. When
they were finished the venerable Chinese gentleman from Taiwan, turned
to me and said, “Mr Thomson, - you have heard what my staff have had
to say. Please take your document away and incorporate all of their
comments and suggestions. Then double your proposed budget, and bring it
back to me.” I did so with some pleasure, as readers can imagine. Dr
Shei was as good as his word, and financed the whole exercise.
However, my own organisation, FAO, which was
offered the task of organising the regional conference and workshop,
(which ADB would have paid them handsomely for), declined to
participate, since they had seen no need to address the fisheries energy
and fuel issue in such a comprehensive way. They were the losers
however, as all other participating governments were enthusiastic,
particularly the Philippines which opened its renewable energy
technology development campus at Cavite, to the conference. The campus
had a range of working units such as fishing boats powered by motors run
on alcohol from sugar cane and palm sugar, as well as other crops. There
were diesel engines adapted to operate on solid wood fuel and charcoal,
through Pyrolitic digesters. Windmills of different designs were pumping
water into fish farm ponds, and solar driers were being used to produce
dried shrimp and fish. Maya farms, a private sector venture on the east
side of Laguna de Bay, welcomed participants to view their large pig and
chicken farm whose huge freezers and cold stores were powered entirely
by electricity generated from bio-gas.
Other governments that showed interest were
China and Mexico. The Mexican government was hosting a large Latin
American Fisheries Symposium at Cancun later that year. To my surprise
they invited me to attend and present a similar paper. I was well
received, and seated at the head table between the Ministers of
Fisheries for China and Peru. The meeting debated my paper and accepted
its proposals almost unanimously. The only dissenting voices came from
the delegates from the UK and France. My own organisation continued to
act petulantly and had insisted the only way I could address the
conference was by taking leave and doing so entirely at my own expense.
But the Mexican government covered all my local hotel costs. I went
through FAO headquarters 2 months later and was somewhat amused to have
officials there say how good it was I had been the one FAO officer to be
at that important event ! However, that is all history and we let
bygones be bygones.
To come back to the present time, we are
facing serious fuel costs and credit restrictions which will place major
constraints on fishery operations all over the world. How are we to
address them ? In the short term there will be much pain and many
bankruptcies. That is not avoidable. Farming and other food sectors will
also suffer, along with manufacturing. But we can and must begin to
develop sustainable technologies for the 21st
century. We need boats that consume modest amounts of fuel, just as we
need motor cars that do the same. This is quite possible, but requires
political will and fisher commitment. Fishing methods adopted for the
future must be such that require minimum power and have no adverse
impacts on the marine environment. To counter the high cost of
borrowing, fishing units of the future should be of low capital cost.
And governments must cease to add high artificial costs to vessel
operations. If there are to be payments for fish quotas, they should be
made after the fish are sold, and made through government or fisher
associations, into accounts established to support conservation and help
new entrants to the industry. Likewise fishing boat licenses should be
set at levels adequate to cover the cost of vessel inspection and safety
services like lighthouses and radio beacons, along with contributions
from the merchant ships.
Hopefully at some point in the future,
application of these concepts will minimise the number of fisher
bankruptcies, and put and end to visits of struggling crews and skippers
to the fish salesmen’s or bank managers’ “chamber of horrors”.
|