Around five centuries ago a crew of fishers
sailed their small open boat into the Spynie Loch near my present home,
from the shores of the Moray Firth. At that time the loch was open to
the sea, and boats could sail up to the foot of Spynie Palace, or to the
moat around Duffus Castle to the north-west. Silting and the build-up of
sand-dunes that occurred in the 16th
and 17th
centuries, along with draining of the loch in the 18th
and 19th
centuries, closed the access to the sea, and left little more than a
ditch and a bog where the great loch had been. But in the middle ages
the lagoon-like coastal loch was suitable for shallow draft boats to
traverse. Its crystal waters fostered populations of sole, plaice, eel,
prawns, crabs, and attracted schools of whiting, haddock, mackerel,
sprat and herring in their season. But medieval feudal law gave the
harvesting rights, or taxation authority over those living resources, to
the local barons and bishops.
The fishers pulled down their ragged sail
and rowed the last half-mile to the shore. There they started to unload
their modest catch of cod and haddock taken by hand-line. They were poor
men, and the few fish they caught would help feed their wives and
children, with a small surplus they could sell on the Elgin market, or
barter for oatmeal or potatoes. For myself, reading the skeleton account
we have, which is almost a by-note in the local annals of the parish, I
often wondered what life was like for such serfs. Where did they live ?
What kind of clothes did they wear? Did they suffer from malnutrition?
Would their damp drafty smokey hovels have encouraged tuberculosis,
rheumatism, or infestation by lice or fleas? What was their normal life
span? Could they read or write? What kind of world view did they have?
Whatever the life these simple fishers had,
on this particular day their activity and movements had been spotted by
the greedy eyes of the Bishop and his officers. Apparently the feudal
arrangements that gave the king and his barons the right to all the deer
and fauna of the forest, also extended (in their view), to the fish of
the sea. (They may well had parts of Feudal law support their view, but
even the King traditionally claimed only salmon from the rivers and
sturgeon from the sea). Whether the fishermen were ignorant of the
bishop’s claims, we do not know. Certainly there was little apparent
attempt to hide their boat or its small catch. But the men were seized
and jailed on the orders of the bishop, and their catch confiscated.
What happened to them, their boat, and their families, we can but
speculate. The ancient record says little beyond their arrest.
Laying claim to the sea’s harvests was a
regular feature of governments and rulers in centuries past. They did
not purchase them or work for them or earn them by their contribution to
the welfare of the people. Mostly they were assumed by autocratic rulers
and if allocated to their barons or governors, it was done in return for
their loyalty or a share of the proceeds obtained.
In 1609 the King of England granted Fernando
Georges who founded New Hampshire, the right to the fish on the
lucrative grounds offshore, - later named Georges Bank after him. In his
case it did not work out as he was simply unable to enforce the monopoly
on the stormy open waters of the East Atlantic.
However not all past government
interventions if fisheries were punitive or unjust. The importance of
herring as a winter food for the population, (and for its soldiers and
sailors), led the Dutch government to promote the huge drift net fishery
in the North Sea in the 16th
and 17th
centuries, and the British government to take similar steps in the next
two centuries. Harbours were constructed, fishing boats constructed in
large numbers, salt-curing stations equipped, quality assurance systems
put in place with financial incentives, net manufacture encouraged, and
naval protection extended to the fleet at sea. One result of all the
developments was that practically all of Europe and Scandinavia was kept
afloat on a sea of herring. Salt herring became a major export item and
income earner. The commodity assumed strategic importance as a key
element in the provisions to maintain the large armies and navies of
those times.
Just as the Soviets were to conclude in the
later 20th
century, the maritime states of Europe reckoned that an ocean-ranging
fleet was a military and diplomatic asset to extend their influence to
far-away lands. Before Christopher Columbus made his epic voyage to the
Americas, he sailed on fishing vessels as far north as the Arctic
Circle, and possibly to Jan Mayen Island. The boats he sailed on were
live-well line-fishing craft from Bristol and other English ports. Their
catch was mainly cod, ling, halibut, and hake. When British boats began
to fish around Newfoundland, the navy was there to monitor their
operations and to prevent the growth of an indigenous fishery being
established in Canada. Each autumn ships of the British navy sailed
around the bays and coves of Newfoundland, and burned down the
fishermen’s summer camps in a less than successful effort to ensure that
none of the fishers over-wintered on the island.
All the great maritime nations fostered
large ocean ranging fishing fleets. Spain and Portugal were no
exception. When I first went to Newfoundland in 1965, the magnificent
natural harbour at St. John’s was home to many of the majestic fleet of
sailing schooners that fished for cod off Labrador during the summer
months. Each schooner carried dozens of sailing dories that operated
with one or two men who hand-lined for cod up to several miles from the
mother-ship, much as Rudyard Kipling described in Captain’s
Courageous. Kipling’s story, popularized in the film that starred
Spencer Tracy, described the similar operations of north American cod
schooners from Boston and New Bedford. While the Portuguese schooners
were square-rigged vessels, the American ships were faster, more slender
boats, built for speed, and the ability to sail close to the wind. One
of the most famous, the Bluenose, is still preserved in working
order in Nova Scotia. Some schooner captains well still around in
Newfoundland when I served there in the 1960’s and they were a
marvellous source of nautical information. They also possessed a wisdom
and decency that was typical of their generation, but which is sadly
absent among the social climbers and get-rich-quick merchants that
modern capitalism has produced in disturbing numbers.
The mid-19th
to mid-20th
centuries were the days of the great trade in salt cod, the fish being
split and dried in the sun and wind on shore. They were packed in salt
in the Portuguese ships which made longer voyages than the U.S. and
Canadian boats. The salt cod trade, still very buoyant and profitable in
Spain and Portugal, was killed by a foolish measure a few years prior to
my arrival in Newfoundland. A short-sighted fisheries minister abolished
the quality cull that had grouped the produce into prime, medium, and
poor quality selections. Instead of improving quality, all of the
Canadian fish deteriorated into poor quality, and eventually became
unfit for even the low-price markets of West Africa and the Caribbean.
Today you will still find salt cod being sold in both those regions, but
none of it comes from Canada.
Canada’s great cod fishery which was
exploited sustainably by generations of fishermen like old Captain
Williams, was to be destroyed in a few short years from 1970 to 1990
after the Federal Department of Fisheries yielded to the monetarist
attitudes that treated fisheries as if they were an industrial sector
like car manufacture or house construction. Increased effort in the form
of powerful stern trawlers and purse seiners, was encouraged, and the
concentration of fishing rights and fish harvesting in their hands, made
possible by ITQs, tradable fish quotas, that facilitated the buying and
selling of access to fish stocks which were placed on the market like
sacrificial lambs. Within 20 years, the cod stock collapsed and the
inshore fishery was wiped off the map. The companies that owned the
stern trawlers could organize legal ways to reduce their losses. They
could shift to another more profitable sector to invest in. But as has
happened in so many parts of the world, the indigenous coastal fishers
paid the heaviest price. What Oliver Goldsmith wrote of the Deserted
Village, could apply to the deserted out-ports and islands of the
Maritimes.
Next to cod, hake has traditionally been the
most prized of the white fish, on the Spanish markets. Both Spain and
Portugal developed pareja or paranzella pair trawlers to
fish for hake in deep water in the north-east Atlantic. The European
hake (merlucias species) are quite different from west
Atlantic hake. They are high-swimming bottom fish, usually found above
sandy or muddy sea-bed, in depths up to several hundreds of fathoms. By
using two boats the Spaniards were able to trawl without otter boards,
and to use a large well-floated net with a high mouth-opening. They also
used long warps to herd the schools of hake towards the net. For many
years these pair trawlers operated off the west coasts of Ireland and
Scotland. I used to watch them with great interest when spending a
summer as a cabin boy on my own father’s vessel fishing off the west of
Ireland. In those days the Spanish fishermen were poor, - their clothes
well patched, - and their boats also showed the signs of minimal
maintenance. Many were powered by steam engines then.
Today most of Spain’s hake comes from
Namibia. The fish are vital as raw material, and to maintain employment
in the fish processing sector in Spain where there are 800 companies and
22,500 employees. Spanish boats fished off South-West Africa until it
gained independence as Namibia. Then the European Union tried to force
the fledgling SWAPO government to permit continued access to Namibian
grounds for the huge EU fleet. The government was threatened with loss
of aid from Europe if it resisted. (I know this well having been present
at the negotiations in Windhoek). But Minister Helmut Angula stood firm,
and only ships under Namibian registration were permitted. The Spanish
authorities then saw reason, and the largest company, Pescanova, set up
a joint venture with a local fishing company. They built a large factory
in Luderitz and had the fleet that serviced it put under Namibian flag
and registration. On behalf of the Ministry of Fisheries, Namibia, I
helped to organize the training scheme for national crews and officers
to help man the fleet and the processing plant.
Together, the fishing fleet and fish
processing sector of Namibia, grew to become the industrial sector with
the largest employment in the country, and overtook mining which till
then had been the major employer. Fish exports also became the country’s
major source of foreign currency.
The over-capitalisation of fishing fleets
that occurred in the later 20th
century, required serious attention, but governments in the northern
hemisphere tended to protect the guilty and punish the innocent. Those
countries which built their fish allocation policies on ITQs or tradable
quotas, rewarded the companies which had added most tonnage and power to
over-capacity, and let the low-impact small scale fleets pay the price
for further concentration of fishery access and fishing rights in the
hands of the rich and powerful. Canada, Iceland and New Zealand, led the
way in this regard. In Iceland’s case the government were taken to the
court of human rights by coastal fishermen who had been disadvantaged.
But the worst example of bad governance in
fisheries must surely be the EU, the European Union and its CFP or
Common Fisheries Policy which attempted to manage the fishing grounds
and fishing fleets of all its members, from the eastern Mediterranean,
to the North Sea, 200 miles west and north of Ireland and the Shetland
Isles. The results, over the past 30 years, have been disastrous by any
measure one cares to use. Instead of conserving resources, the CFP
caused the destruction of up to 600,000 tonnes a year by its doctrinaire
application of single species quotas in a multi-species fishery, coupled
to an insistence on dumping or discarding all fish caught excess to that
species quota, for each boat involved. The British government went along
with this despite strong protests from its fishers, and even agreed to
scrap the minimum sizes for fish landed for human consumption. |