POPULAR tradition, and
even literary tradition have come to associate all the great
Scottish emigration movements with poverty and distress. This is
particularly so of emigrations from the Highlands. The mere mention
of them suggests at once rackrents, brutal landlords, and evictions.
In the face of this prevailing impression, it is worth while to
analyse the nature and the causes of the first great exodus from the
Highlands, an exodus which reached its highest point of activity in
the early seventies of the eighteenth century.
Emigration from Scotland was of course not new. To judge from the
dispatches of the colonial governors, before the eighteenth century
was well begun the Scots were already penetrating into most of the
English plantations. They brought with them both their business
instincts and their zest for Presbyterianism, and everywhere their
trail is marked by newly planted kirks and flourishing settlements.
Even the last outposts of the English in America, the frontiers of
the new plantation of Georgia, depended for part of their defence
upon the little settlement of Mackintoshes from Inverness.
But this emigration, considerable as it must have been, was a
gradual process, and went on comparatively unheeded, whereas the
violent outburst that followed close after the middle of the century
drew attention at once, and was hailed by travelers, statesmen, and
patriotic writers as a new and startling phenomenon.
Roughly speaking, the phase referred to may be said to have lasted
from 1740 to 1775. Knox in his View of the Highlands (pub. 1784)
suggests 1763 as the earliest date, but there are several reasons
for putting it earlier. Pennant in his Travels gives 1750 as the
starting-point for Skye. A letter in the Culloden Papers hints at
emigration from the Western Islands as far back as 1740, while the
Scots Magazine as early as 1747 had begun to take notice of the
spread of emigration. The latter reached its zenith in the early
seventies, and in 1775 received a decided check, which is attributed
by most contemporaries to the general effects of the American War,
and by Knox to a particular order of Congress. The lull which
followed lasted almost ten years.
The emigrants were drawn from a fairly wide area. Perthshire and
Strathspey contributed a few; the mainland districts of Argyllshire,
Ross, and Sutherland contributed more; but the bulk of the mainland
emigration was supplied by the glens of Inverness-shire, Strathglass,
Glenmoriston, Glengarry, and Glen Urquhart.
The really sensational departures, however, were not from the
mainland but from the islands; and the places that figure most
largely in the records of the exodus are Skye, the two Uists, Lewes,
Arran, Jura, Gigha, and Islay.
A few districts in America received the emigrants. Some, but not
many, went to Georgia. To the majority the desired havens appear to
have been the Carolinas, Albany, and Nova Scotia. To estimate the
actual numbers that went is a matter of extreme difficulty. The
sources of information are vague.
From the Old Statistical Account we gather that before 1775
emigration had taken place from some sixteen Highland parishes; the
Scots Magazine in the numbers published before 1775 contains twenty
definite references to ships leaving with Highland emigrants, apart
from the mention of emigration projects which may or may not have
materialised; and a variety of rather indefinite evidence bearing on
the subject is supplied by the Privy Council Papers relating to the
Colonies, the Scottish Forfeited Estates Papers, and innumerable
contemporary writers and periodicals.
Occasionally the embarkation would take place from a regular port,
like Glasgow or Greenock, and be duly noted, but more often the
emigrants set sail as unobtrusively as possible from some lonely
Highland loch. Gigha, the Skye ports, Campbelltown, Dunstaffnage
Bay, Fort William, Maryburgh, Stornaway, Loch Broom, Loch Erribol,
and even Thurso and Stromness all figure as collecting centres and
points of embarkation.
Under these circumstances the numbers become in the highest degree
conjectural. Two estimates, however, were hazarded, by men who were
almost, or quite, contemporaries of the movement. Knox gives as his
figure 20,000 between 1763 and 1773, while Garnett in his Tour (pub.
1800) states that 30,000 emigrated between 1773 and 1775. The latter
estimate seems almost certainly exaggerated, and it is not easy to
find satisfactory corroboration of even Knox’s figures. The
statistics furnished by the Old Statistical Account and the
miscellaneous sources are mostly too vague to be of much help. Our
most reliable guide is certainly the Scots Magazine, which has the
advantage of being contemporary, and of recording the emigrations as
they occur. Yet if we add together all the Highland departures
before 1775 chronicled by the Scots Magazine, the total is something
under 10,000 persons. No doubt the entries in the magazine are not
exhaustive, but allowing for some omissions the discrepancy between
its figures and those of Garnett, and even of Knox, is very great.
A partial explanation of the latter’s estimate might be found in the
recruiting records of the period. Many Highlanders left the country
as soldiers. A writer in the Scots Magazine of October, 1775,
calculated that upwards of 9500 had been thus drawn from the
Highlands, and of these many, like Fraser’s Highlanders, eventually
found homes in the New World, and might be counted in a sense
emigrants.
Both at the time and later there seems then to have been a tendency
to exaggerate the numbers of those emigrating at this stage. The
emigrants were not many, and if this seems difficult to reconcile
with the great agitation expressed at their going, the explanation
can be found in the social standing and comparative wealth of the
leaders of the movement.
That the emigrants included a large percentage of persons possessed
of some capital is everywhere abundantly testified. The Scots
Magazine generally gives in its entries some description of the
emigrants, but only two or three times does it refer to their
poverty, and once when it does, the emigrants set sail from
Stranraer, and were almost certainly not Highland. The only
allusions in fact to the poverty of Highland emigrants appear in
connection with those from Sutherland.
What weight can be attached to such references is doubtful, for
elsewhere we read in the Scots Magazine of September, 1772, that the
persons emigrating from Sutherland between 1768 and 1772 took with
them not less than £10,000 in specie. Now if it is borne in mind
that the total number of emigrants from that area between these
dates was only 500 or 600, and of these a very large percentage were
women and children, it is obvious that many of the heads of
households must have been persons of substance.
Possibly the allusions to their poverty can be explained by the fact
that they, almost alone of the emigrants, passed through Edinburgh
on their way abroad. There they became at once an object of interest
and compassion, and their unusual appearance and pathetic situation
no doubt supplied to Lowland eyes sufficient evidence of distress.
Apart from this doubtful case of the Sutherland people, there is no
suggestion that the Highland emigrants were being driven by acute
poverty. The Scots Magazine normally refers to them in such phrases
as ‘people in good circumstances,’ ‘gentlemen of wealth and merit,’
‘people of property,’ and so on.
The impression thus given is confirmed by the mention of the amount
of capital they took with them. As a typical example the 425 persons
who sailed from Maryburgh in 1773 took £6000 with them in ready
cash, while in a number of the Edinburgh Advertiser, dated January
17, 1792, it was stated that since 1772 £38,000 had been taken from
the country by the emigrants from West Ross-shire and
Inverness-shire alone.
It must be granted, then, that at least the leaders of the movement
of the seventies were reasonably prosperous people. Knowing that
they were strongly attached to their native land, and that they were
not driven out by stress of poverty, the question naturally arises
what induced them to go?
In answer to this question various suggestions have been put forward
both at the time of the emigrations and afterwards.
If we disregard vague and unsubstantiated generalisations about the
tyranny of landlords, these suggestions reduce themselves to the
following five: the union of farms for sheep; the redundancy of the
population; the effect of the Jacobite rebellions; the influence of
the returned Highland soldier; and finally the rise in rents.
The first suggestion is rarely, if ever, mentioned in actual
contemporaries. It is generally put forward in works written twenty
years later, while a new and entirely different emigration movement
was in progress. It cannot provide any satisfactory explanation for
the period of the seventies, for in the districts most affected by
emigration the introduction of sheep had then hardly begun.
The second suggestion comes nearer the truth. The Highlands
economically utilised may have been capable of providing for all
their population, but as things were, numbers had no proper
employment and lived permanently upon the edge of subsistence. That
was becoming increasingly true and increasingly obvious, and was
soon to result in emigration on an altogether unprecedented scale.
But no more than the first does this explain the prosperous
emigration of the seventies. The well-to-do farmer who sublet his
lands, as practically all did, was in the first instance a gainer
rather than a loser by a phenomenon which created an intense and
feverish competition for land, and which in so doing sent up the
rents and services paid to himself.
The Jacobite Rebellions, and the influence of the Highland soldiers,
have both a genuine effect upon emigration. Highland families whose
fortunes had been broken in the ’45, and who regarded land as an
essential of existence, turned naturally to America, and in going
took numbers of their old dependents with them. Thus John Macdonald
of Glenaladale having been obliged to sell his estate in consequence
of difficulties following the ’45, left Scotland in 1772 with 200
Highlanders for Prince Edward Island, but such cases are rather
isolated.
The Highland regiments had also a distinctly stimulating effect. The
habit of planting ex-soldiers in America led to the establishment of
a connection between the Highlands and Nova Scotia and Albany. The
letters and encouragement sent home by the soldiers are frequently
mentioned as promoting emigration. But even this is rather an
additional stimulus than a real cause. A prosperous family of
well-established social connections does not readily tear itself up
by the roots simply because it happens to hear hopeful accounts of a
new world. Some stronger incentive was needed to urge on the leaders
of the movement, though doubtless the influence of the soldiers
simplified the work of persuading some of the poorer folk to go with
them.
There is left then as a possible real cause the general rise of
rents in the Highlands, and this is the explanation put forward most
frequently to account for the emigrations.
Pennant refers to it repeatedly. It appears again in the writings of
Knox, in Heron’s Observations (pub. 1792), in Walker’s Economical
History of the Hebrides (1808), in the Privy Council Papers, in the
Parliamentary Debates of the period, in the Old Statistical Account,
and elsewhere.
But while most authorities agree in mentioning the rise in rents as
a cause of emigration, the manner in which they make mention of the
fact varies indefinitely. Some regard the rise in rents as a piece
of absolutely indefensible tyranny; some like Pennant deplore the
consequences, but suggest at least a partial justification for the
landlord in the corresponding rise of cattle prices; while there are
others, like the writers in the Farmers' Magazine, who go so far as
to regard the rise as a benefit to the Highlands, since it compelled
the adoption of more modern and economical systems of cultivation.
Who were the persons primarily affected by this rise in rents, and
what was the nature of the rents previously paid?
In answer to the first question, there can be little doubt that the
people immediately affected by the rise were the superior tenants,
who in Highland estate economy occupied a position not dissimilar to
that of feudal tenants-in-chief. On many estates the landlord does
not appear to have come into direct contact with the smaller tenants
or cottagers. They held from the superior tenants, the tacksmen, and
could only receive an increase of rents by the landlords,
indirectly, and from the evidence that follows it will seem very
doubtful whether the under tenant could have paid more for his land
than he was already doing.
But the same is emphatically not true of the rent paid by the
tacksmen.
The position of the tacksmen was peculiar. A definition is given of
the term in Carlisle’s Topographical Description of Scotland (pub.
1813), which runs as follows: ‘One who holds a lease from another, a
tenant of a higher class:—this term is usually used in
contradistinction to Tenants in general, who are such as rent only a
Portion of a Farm.’
Normally the special emphasis is laid on the holding of a long lease
or tack—a tenure which in early days might be taken as a definite
mark of social as well as economic superiority.
Generally speaking the original holders of the tacks were the
younger sons of the chiefs, who found that to grant farms on long
leases and extremely moderate rents was the simplest if not the only
possible method of providing for their large families. As might be
expected, the social prestige of the holders was therefore great.
‘The class of tacksmen occupy nearly the same rank in the Hebrides
as belongs to that of men of landed property in other parts of
Britain. They are called Gentlemen, and appear as such; and obtain a
title from the farm which they hold, nearly in the same manner as
gentlemen in other parts of the country obtain from their estates.’1
Almost all references to them, even when abusive as those made by
Burt, by Buchanan and by Duncan Forbes, still make use of the term
‘gentlemen.’ They prided themselves upon the upkeep of a crowd of
dependents, and the support of a constant and lavish hospitality.
Indeed, so far as we can gather from Pennant and the Gartmore MSS.
their personal habits and mode of life were strikingly similar to
those of the chiefs.
1 An Account of the Present State of the Hebrides and West Coasts of
Scotland, James Anderson, 1785.
The relations of the tacksmen and the proprietors were naturally
strongly coloured by the social and kinship ties which bound them
together. All the evidence we have from Pennant, who describes the
state of things before the transition, to Buchanan, who in his
Travels in the Western Hebrides is writing between 1782-1790 of
those districts where the tacksmen still survived, confirms the
belief that the leases were originally granted on terms abnormally
favourable to the holders.
‘The tacksmen,’ says Anderson (1785), ‘were treated with a mildness
that made them consider their leases rather as a sort of property,
subjected to a moderate quitrent to their superior, than as a fair
and full rent for land in Scotland.’
The normal acquiescence of the proprietor in this view was not, of
course, due primarily to sentimental attachments. As is well known,
Highland estate values before the eighteenth century were reckoned
not in money but in men. In the military organisation of the clan,
the tacksmen formed an essential element, since by blood, instincts,
and training they were its natural lieutenants. As such they were
indispensable to the chief, and they paid for their lands in full by
their services. Their money rents were altogether a minor matter,
and not being fixed by any economic considerations, bore no
necessary relation to the economic value of the land.
Once military services became obsolete, and the rent was the sole
return made by the tacksman for his land, the revision of rents by
the landlord was inevitable. Even if there had been no special
causes at work, such as the rise in cattle prices, rents must still
have risen to correspond to the altered social conditions of the
Highlands.
But there are other considerations that also influence the
eighteenth century proprietor. The decay of the military side of the
clan system left him viewing the tacksman as an expensive and
altogether unnecessary luxury on a generally poor estate. For not
only did he pay an inadequate rent, but he possessed several other
drawbacks that struck most forcibly those landlords who had some
ideas on estate improvement.
The tacksmen were bad farmers. Pennant, who is always most
sympathetic towards them, admits candidly that they had not the
habits of industry. Their establishments were frankly medieval, and
as Pennant himself said, the number of labourers they maintained
resembled a retinue of retainers rather than the number required for
the economical management of a farm. Forty years later Macdonald, in
the Agricultural Report of the Hebrides (pub. 1811), confirms this
view. Macdonald is normally most moderate in his statements, but he
is emphatic in the opinion that the tacksmen, despite their many
virtues and accomplishments, had been largely instrumental in
holding back the agricultural progress of the Highlands. Exceptions
existed, but the average tacksman appeared to regard himself as
superior to the drudgery of farm work, while his natural
conservatism was a bar to all improvements. The first step towards
any progress in the eyes of Macdonald was the resumption by the
proprietor of direct control over his estates, and direct relations
with his under tenants.
This brings us to the second serious charge made against the
tacksmen. Evidence abounds to prove that the tacksmen were not good
masters. Exorbitant rents, heavy services, and insecurity of tenure
are the characteristic marks of their dealings with their under
tenants. With the ethics of such practices we are not for the moment
concerned. The proprietor may have objected to them on purely moral
grounds, it is certain that he regarded them as an economic
grievance. By lavish subletting, or in the contemporary phrase
subsetting, a tacksman might live rent free, while the proprietor
could only look on and see his estate reduced to beggary by the
sweating practices already mentioned. A good landlord could not but
resent a system so hostile to the bulk of his tenants; a bad
landlord could not but chafe at a practice so entirely unprofitable
to himself.
One of the earliest pieces of evidence we have on the subject is
contained in a report, dated ,1737, which was sent by Duncan Forbes
of Culloden to the Duke of Argyll. The report concerned certain
estates of the latter which Forbes had been sent to inspect with a
view to the possibility of improvements. The following is a
quotation: ‘The unmerciful exaction of the late tacksman is the
cause of those lands (i.e. of the Island of Coll) being waste, which
had it continued but for a very few years longer would have entirely
unpeopled the island. They speak of above one hundred familys that
have been reduced to beggary and driven out of the island within
these last seven years.’ . . . ‘But though your Grace’s expectations
or mine may not be answered as to the improvement of the rent, yet
in this, I have satisfaction, and it may be some to you, that the
method taken has prevented the totall ruin of these islands, and the
absolute loss of the whole rent in time coming to your Grace, had
the tacksmen been suffered to continue their extortions a few years
longer these islands would have been dispeopled, and you must have
been contented with no rent, or with such as these harpies should be
graciously pleased to allow you.’
Further corroborative evidence is found in the British Museum MSS.
dated 1750 (edited Lang), which, after detailing various acts of
oppression, laid down the conviction of the author that the
Highlands could not be improved until the tacksmen either were
deprived of their power of subsetting or held it under conditions
which would protect the interests of the under tenants, or better
still, were only allowed to keep such land as they and their
personal servants were able to cultivate.
It must not be thought that the oppressive practices detailed by
Forbes and the anonymous writer were simply the lingering relics of
a past age. Where the tacksmen continue in existence, the abuses
appear to have continued also even to the end of the century and
later.
An English traveller writing from his personal observation in 1785
makes the following statement:
‘The chieftain lets out his land in large lots to the inferior
branches of the family, all of whom must support the dignity of
lairds. The renters let the land out in small parcels from year to
year to the lower class of people, and to support their dignity,
squeeze everything out of them they can possibly get, leaving them
only a bare subsistence. Until this evil is obviated Scotland can
never improve.’
The Old Statistical Account gives some cases referring to the same
period. In Harris while the small tenants directly under the
proprietor had leases, those under the tacksmen paid more rent and
held at will. In Edderachylis, while the proprietor had abandoned
all claims to personal services, the tacksmen exacted them so
rigorously that they were able to dispense entirely with any hired
labour. However extravagant the demands, no tenant holding at will,
as all did, dared to refuse them, for no tacksman would have
received on his lands the rebellious tenant of another.
The writer on the parish of Tongue drew a similar comparison between
the conduct of the proprietor and the tacksmen. He appealed to the
authority of the former to restrain the merciless exactions of the
latter, which left their tenants with neither time nor energy to
cultivate their own farms. The tacksmen, he held, were little better
than West Indian slave drivers-
But the heaviest indictment of all is that which appears in
Buchanon’s Travels. Buchanon was a Church of Scotland missionary,
and the Travels are the result of his personal observations of
Hebridean conditions between 1782 and 1790. The proprietors are
referred to in terms of high praise, but the tacksmen incur
Buchanon’s unqualified condemnation.
‘The land is parcelled out in small portions by the tacksmen among
the immediate cultivators of the soil, who pay their rent in kind
and in personal services. Though the tacksmen for the most part
enjoy their leases of whole districts on liberal terms, their
exactions from the subtenants are in general most severe. They grant
them their possessions only from year to year, and lest they should
forget their dependent condition, they are every year at a certain
term, with the most regular formality, ordered to quit their
tenements and to go out of the bounds of the leasehold estate . . .
there is not perhaps any part of the world where the good things of
this life are more unequally distributed. While the scallag and the
subtenant are wholly at the mercy of the tacksman, the tacksman from
a large and advantageous farm, the cheapness of every necessary, and
by means of smuggling every luxury, rolls in ease and affluence.’
We may conclude from these accounts, which might be amplified
indefinitely, that the lower classes in the Highlands did not stand
to lose by any change which transferred them from the power of the
tacksmen to that of the owner.
To the unsentimental observer the whole system of which the tacksman
was a part appeared a hopeless anachronism. The tacksmen were
superfluous middlemen who farmed badly, paid inadequate rents, and
by oppressive services prevented the under tenants from attending
properly to their farms.
No landowner just becoming alive to the economic possibilities of
his estates could reasonably be expected to allow the system to
continue. Some tried to remedy matters by raising the rents of the
tacksmen as they got the opportunity. In not a few such cases, owing
sometimes to the greed of the proprietor, sometimes to his
ignorance, and most often to want of proper estate surveys, the
rents were raised too high. Raising rents, however, is only one
symptom of a general transition. So long as the tacksmen had the
power to shift their burdens on to the shoulders of their under
tenants, a mere rise in their rentals could supply no adequate
solution for the landlord’s problems. There is a case, for example,
mentioned in the Caledonian Mercury of 1781, of a tacksman holding
lands near Lochgilphead. During the entire period of his lease, he
had, by subsetting, received always more rent than he had to pay.
If the tacksmen were to be brought to fulfil a real economic
function in the estate system, there had to be changes more drastic
than rent raising, and the more advanced landowners were alive to
this fact. The decay or the destruction of the tacksman system did
not proceed rapidly. It was not even complete by the end of the
eighteenth century. Sometimes it was held back by sentimental
considerations, the still surviving tie of kinship or the pride of
raising family regiments. Sometimes it was due to the poverty of the
proprietor and his real economic dependence on the tacksmen. Cases
exist when the tacksmen possessed all the movable stock on an
estate, and were therefore more or less indispensable to its
running. Sometimes the slowness is due to mere geographical
situation, remote areas perhaps not receiving the influx of new
ideas until late in the century.
Still the changes went on, and what concerns us chiefly was their
peculiar activity about the sixties and seventies. To avoid
misunderstanding let us be quite clear as to what the changes
implied. The elimination of the tacksmen did not mean necessarily
the elimination of the individuals who formed the class, nor did it
mean the elimination of leaseholders.
Under the new system leases are granted, but granted on rents which
represent, or are intended to represent, the economic value of the
land. These leases are granted to a much wider class, and so far
diminish the profit and the prestige of those who had formerly held
tacks. Again, the practice of subsetting was abolished, or the
services which might be exacted from subtenants limited. Some of the
subtenants were promoted at once to the dignity of leaseholders.
Finally the whole relations of landlord and tacksmen were put on a
simple business footing, thereby extinguishing the tacksman’s
partial sense of ownership, and the half-traditional tie of kinship.
The tacksmen, in fact, ceased to form a special and privileged
class. Their status was lowered as that of the under tenants was
raised.
Such were the changes that the more advanced landowners were aiming
at throughout the period of the first emigration. How they were
carried out we can gather from the records of the Argyll estates. In
the early part of the eighteenth century certain lands in Mull,
Tyree, and Morven which had been for several centuries under the
chief of the Clan M‘Lean, fell into the hands of the reigning Duke
of Argyll, who in 1732 sent Campbell of Stonefield to investigate
and report upon his newly acquired estates.
Campbell reported that the subtenants complained bitterly of the
oppression of the tacksmen. This state of things Campbell proposed
to alter, partly by raising the more substantial subtenants to the
rank of tacksmen ; partly by compelling the tacksmen to give leases
to their under tenants ; and partly by drawing up a fixed statement
of the services the tacksmen might exact. An attempt was made also
to commute the more oppressive services into money rents, and as
Campbell himself was not a judge of local land values, and could not
count on disinterested advice from anyone, he took the only method
of fixing rents open to him, that was to invite the farmers to bid
for their possessions.
It is not probable that all Campbell’s ideas were put into practice.
Campbell himself may not have possessed full powers, and the leases
of the tacksmen could not in any case be altered until they fell in
for renewal. Accordingly, we find Duncan Forbes being sent in 1737
on a similar mission to that of Campbell, a mission which resulted
in the report from which we have already quoted. Forbes’ policy runs
on lines similar to that of Campbell, and he gives graphic details
of the tacksmen’s efforts to defeat his plans and unite their under
tenants in an elaborate conspiracy against their own interests.
These examples, occurring earlier than most, are yet typical of the
changes that begin to take place on many Highland estates. Tacksmen
soon after the middle of the century found themselves continually
faced with the prospect of heightened rents and lowered social
position.
Some remained and adapted themselves to the new conditions ; a few
became successful farmers of a more modern type. Many of them,
however, clung resolutely to the habits of their fathers, and rather
than acquiesce in the changes, tried to transfer themselves and
their whole social system to the New World.
The point of view of the tacksman is thus stated, somewhat
unsympathetically, in an article which appeared in the Edinburgh
Advertiser in 1772
‘Such of these wadsetters and tacksmen as rather wish to be
distinguished as leaders, than by industry, have not taken leases
again, alleging that the rents are risen above what the land will
bear ; but,’ say they, ‘ in order to be revenged on our masters for
doing so, and what is worse depriving us of our subordinate
chieftainship by abolishing our former privilege of subsetting, we
will not only leave his lands, but by spiriting the lower class of
people to emigrate, we shall carry a class to America, and when they
are there they must work for us or starve.’
To say why the under tenants went might involve an elaborate study
of the psychology of the Highlanders. We can only suggest here that
the habits of obedience engendered for generations were not easily
overcome, while the report of Duncan Forbes on conditions in Mull
showed how apparently easy it was for the ignorant under tenants to
be persuaded by the tacksmen into courses almost obviously opposed
to their own interests.
Such were the causes and the manner ot the emigration of the
seventies, a movement which deprived the Highlands of a considerable
number of its influential men and a still greater proportion of its
available capital. The movement has been often misrepresented both
by eighteenth century and by modern writers. As recently as 1914 we
find an author in the December number of the Celtic Review treating
the whole incident along traditional lines, the poverty and absolute
helplessness of the emigrants being contrasted with the brutality
and greed of the landowners.
But such a view is not in harmony with what we have been able to
discover of the facts. We would go further and say that in many
respects the Highlands gained rather than lost by this particular
emigration movement. Putting aside the purely sentimental writers,
those who have lamented most the departure of the tacksmen appear to
have been influenced less by the thought of what they were than by
the dream of what they might have become. The possibilities of the
tacksmen system have for the Highland reformer an almost
irresistible attraction. The tacksmen had the glamour of tradition
behind them. They were picturesque. They had the pleasing appearance
of bridging the social gulf between owner and crofter. They had some
education, some capital, and the habit of leadership, of all which
qualities the eighteenth century Highlands stood in need.
But the value of this to the community was potential rather than
real. In practice, the tacksman’s capital was a means of oppression
not of development, his leadership led generally in the wrong
direction, while his insistence on lines of social demarcation could
not have been surpassed by the proprietor himself. Rather than lose
his social privileges he emigrated.
Regrettable as was the loss of any good inherent in the tacksmen
system, the gain was greater than the loss, and the regret expended
on the emigration of the seventies is a tribute to romance rather
than to economics.
Margaret I. Adam |