IT was not in Agriculture alone that the great
principle of giving free scope to individual Mind, and to individual
Capital, which is its fruit, became the prime agent in the advancing
prosperity of Scotland. It was equally conspicuous and equally powerful in
the opening of her Trade and Commerce. In a former chapter' I have referred
to the engrossing Monopolies which had been given by early Charters to the
old Royal Burghs of the country. Those who have been accustomed to think of
Fiscal Protection as specially associated with the interest of Landowners,
have little idea how universally this system originated with the only
popular Bodies which existed in the Military Ages, or of the extravagant
lengths to which commercial exclusiveness was earned on their behalf. For
centuries, and by repeated Statutes, the whole Trade and Commerce of
Scotland were placed in the hands of a few Communities of ancient date, to
the absolute exclusion not only of the whole agricultural classes, but to
the exclusion also of all other Towns and Villages which had arisen from
time to time in situations favourable for some particular kind of industry.
The "liberties" granted to the old Communities were Monopolies in the only
correct sense of that word—the sense, namely, in which it means the absolute
prohibition of all selling and buying by all persons who do not belong to
the privileged Community, so that even their own money and their own goods
are made useless for purposes of exchange except through the narrow circle
of the Monopolists.' Not a single quarter of corn,—not a single beast of any
kind,—not a single cask of wine,—not a single fleece of wool, nor hide of
cattle, could be lawfully imported, or even bought and sold, except through
the hands of the privileged Freemen of the Royal Burghs. Within the Burghs
themselves the Magistrates assumed and exercised the right of regulating and
fixing the prices of all kinds of goods, and especially of bread and
provisions generally. This was done in the assumed interest of the
Community.
Nothing is more remarkable in the History of Scotland
than the manner in which this wide, deeply rooted, and oppressive system was
gradually invaded and destroyed by the natural action of individual
interests, without any previous change of abstract opinion against the
general policy on which the system had been ignorantly founded. So late as
the reign of Charles II. in 1633, a fresh Act was passed renewing, reviving,
and enforcing the older Statutes, and whatever had become more or less
obsolete in these Communal Monopolies over the whole Trade and Commerce of
the Nation.' This was too much. There was an immediate and strong reaction
from the growing energies of individual enterprise and industry. The first
great breach which was effected in the system, came through the undermining
action of the new Towns and Villages which had no old Charters, and were not
included within the charmed circle of the Royal Burghs. The inhabitants of
these places could not practically be prevented from buying and selling such
articles as they were able to make, or—if they were near the sea—to import.
Then came the supporting action of the Landowners on whose Estates these new
Town were rising. They had risen and were growing under the powers and
rights of Leasing, of Feuing, and of Heritable Jurisdiction, which these
Landowners held by Charters erecting their Estates into Baronies of
Regality, or into simple Baronies with powers only a little less extensive.
Hence these new Towns and Communities were called Burghs of Barony and of
Regality. For several centuries there had been more or less of a perpetual
struggle on the part of the Royal Burghs to enforce their monopoly, and to
crush the newer Towns as nests of Smugglers. On the other hand the great
Landowners who held Baronies and Regalities, were naturally interested in
the prosperity of the new Towns which were rising under them, and thus
became insensibly, but very practically, interested in the extension of
individual liberty, and consequently in the freedom of Trade. Accordingly
when legal questions arose, and the Royal Burghs prosecuted other Towns for
violation of their monopolies, the Landowners sometimes appeared in support
of the defence.
The Act of 1633 was too violent to be borne. At last,
in 1671, a case arose which brought matters to a head. Falkirk was a Burgh
of Regality built on the Estate of the Earl of Callendar. But it was within
the area of Monopoly claimed by the Royal Burgh of Stirling. It was
prosecuted for allowing its inhabitants, who were "unfreemen," to engage in
trade. The case attracted great attention. The Barons of Regality took up
arms in a body in favour of a wider liberty. The Duke of Lauderdale himself,
who was interested in the rising Town of Musselburgh, was induced to come to
Edinburgh to watch the case as it was argued before the Court of Session. It
soon appeared that the questions raised touched the whole policy of the
Kingdom, and could only be settled by the Legislature itself. A suggestion
to this effect by Sir George Mackenzie was taken up by the Lords of
Parliament, whose duty it was to prepare Bills; and the result was the Act
of 1672,' which effected a temporary compromise between the interests of
individual freedom and the old Monopolies in the hands of a few popular
Bodies. Parliament declared that the Act of 1633 had extended those
monopolies to a degree "highly prejudicial to the common interest and good
of the Kingdom." Nevertheless, the monopoly of the Royal Burghs was for the
future kept up as regarded both the export and import of many articles of
foreign produce, except in so far as private persons of all ranks might
import them for their own domestic use alone. On the other hand, the export
and sale of all agricultural produce and all native commodities was made
free to all the subjects of the Realm. The new Towns, the Burghs of Regality
and of Barony, were made free to trade in all manufactures of their own, to
export all home produce, and to import many articles required for "tillage
or building;" whilst the retail trade of Markets was made absolutely free.
This was a tremendous breach in the exclusive
privileges of the old Burghal Communities, and it was the opening of a very
wide door for the free action of all individual interests. Accordingly,
against the ever widening consequences of this Act the Royal Burghs, which
alone were represented in Parliament, carried on an unceasing struggle and
protest, loudly calling for its repeal. They did succeed in getting some new
Acts passed after the Revolution, fencing and guarding, by new provisions
and penalties, the exclusive rights which still remained to them as regards
the imports of foreign produce; and at a later date their interest in
Parliament, backed by the influence of traditional feelings and opinions
which were not yet theoretically abandoned, were sufficiently strong to
secure a Clause in the Treaty of Union with England, providing for the
security and continuance of their privileges as they then stood. But too
much freedom had now been granted to keep out the continued and unceasing
pressure of individual Mind. The Courts of Law in all doubtful cases ruled
in favour of freedom in the true sense of that word, the sense, namely, of
individual liberty. The natural right Of every man to exercise his own
faculties in the free disposal of his own means and property, became too
wide an instinct to be compatible with even a faint survival of the
Communist Monopolies. Yet it may well be regarded with surprise, that, so
far as the Statute-Book was concerned, they survived down to our own day. It
was not until 1846 that an Act was passed formally abolishing them, and this
was passed as the resuif of an inquiry by Royal Commission, which reported
that practically they were already dead.
Every step in the long process of self-education
through which the Nation passed in this question of Trade Monopolies, is
full of historical and of political interest. There are two documents which
throw especial light upon that process, which are separate from each other
in date by no more than 35 years. The first belongs to the time of the
Commonwealth—the second belongs to the time of William in. The Protector, as
is well known, contemplated and for a time effected, a complete Union
between England and Scotland, both being under one Government, and
represented in one United Parliament. It is to the credit of the Royal
Burghs of Scotland that a majority of them seem to have voted for Cromwell's
policy, which included as one of its main advantages, complete freedom of
commercial intercourse between all citizens of the Commonwealth. Struck by
the poverty of Scotland and the heavy deficit on its revenue below the cost
of its administration, he sent down an experienced Coiimissioner' to inquire
into the subject, and especially into the condition of the Royal Burghs. His
Report, rendered in 1656, gives an authentic and a very striking account of
the almost abject poverty of the country, and of the miserable narrowness of
its Commerce. He saw at once that much of this scantiness of Trade was
directly connected with the backwardness of Agriculture, and the consequent
want of any products to exchange. This condition of Agriculture again he
ascribed to the ignorance, poverty, and slothfulness of the people. With a
curious insight and perspicacity, he pitched on the most striking symbol of
all the waste he saw, and pointed to a "lazy vagrancy of attending and
following their herds up and down in their pasturage."' There was
consequently no trade from the inland parts. There never had been much ; but
what remained was limited to the seaside, and was confined to a few Ports on
the East coast, and in or near the Estuary of the Clyde. Glasgow had then
only twelve vessels, the biggest of which was 150 tons burden, and most of
which were mere boats. They traded to Ireland with small coals in open boats
of from four to twenty tons, taking back meal, oats, butter, with barrel
staves and hoops. There was a limited trade with France and Norway—coals,
plaiding, salt herring, and salmon being the chief articles, for which they
got some condiments and prunes. Dundee had suffered severely from the Wars.
Her trade had declined, but "though not glorious, yet was not contemptible."
She had ten vessels in all, the biggest 120 tons. Ayr was in a sad
condition, from the silting up of her river and harbour. "The place was
growing every day worse and worse." Newark (now Port-Glasgow) had "some four
or five houses besides the Laird's house of the place." Greenock was just
such another, only a little larger —the people all fishermen and sailors
trading to Ireland and the Isles in open boats; yet in spite of all this
leanness in the land, Cromwell's agent had the perception to see, and did
not omit to mention the "Mercantile genius" of the people.
Such was the description of a stranger, coming from a
wealthier country in 1656. But thirty-five years later we have the
description of the Royal Burghs of Scotland given by themselves. They had
spent many of the -intervening years in vain endeavours to enforce their
monopoly against all their countrymen, and in alternate contests and
negotiations with the Landowners who were encouraging the new, unprivileged,
individual Traders who were rising everywhere. The Restoration of the
Monarchy had brought with it the immediate abandonment and revocation of all
Cromwell's policy, including Free Trade with England. This great outlet was
lost to Scotland—to all her Towns whether "free" or "unfree." All the more
was personal energy and character required for success in the narrowed and
restricted paths of industry. The old Royal Burghs did not advance. At last,
in 1691, they appointed a Committee to inquire and report on the condition,
revenues, resources, and difficulties of every one. A tabulated series of
questions was addressed to each. The result was a series of Reports of the
highest interest in History and in Politics. One broad result stares us in
the face—that almost everywhere the privileged and monopolist Burghs were
stagnant or declining, whilst the new Towns which had no privileges, and
were even heavily handicapped in the race by having to fight against
Communal Monopolies, were as universally prosperous, and were rising every
year in wealth and in importance. Mind, set upon is mettle, was everywhere
triumphing over routine and usage:—Mind, in the selection of new sites—Mind,
in the advantage taken of special opportunities—Mind, in seeing new
openings—and everywhere, Mind freed from the stupid levelling of arbitrary
Guilds.
Nothing can be more striking than the evidence to this
effect. One of the questions asked of all the old Royal Burghs concerned the
number and condition of the New Towns of Barony and Regality which existed
within the area of their Monopoly. The list given is a list of many of the
most important Towns now existing in Scotland. The Royal Burgh of Renfrew
enumerates no less than nine new Burghs of Barony and Regality within "their
precincts," even the smallest of which had "a much more considerable trade"
than themselves. Among these nine we find Paisley, Port- Glasgow, Greenock,
and Gourock. The rising trade of all these places was, if possible, to be
suppressed, and the Royal Burghs universally refer to it as "highly
prejudicial" to their own interests and industry. Even Glasgow was at that
time declining—with nearly five hundred houses "waste," whilst those still
inhabited had fallen nearly one-third in the rents they fetched. The best
houses in Glasgow were at that time worth no more than £8, 6s. a year in
Sterling money. Glasgow bitterly complained of the same neighbouring Towns,
and of some others, which so vexed the soul of Renfrew. In particular, the
little village which was growing up on the shores of "Sir John Shaw's little
Bay," Greenock, was described as having "a very great trade both foreign and
inland, particularly prejudicial to the trade of Glasgow."
And yet in the midst of these stupidities we have a
few evidences that even the Communal Mind was opening to the lessons of
experience. In a few cases men began to see that the action of the human
Will is subject to certain natural laws, and that when enactments run
counter to these, or do not take due note of them, such enactments, however
virtuous in motive, are purely mischievous. Thus in 1688, the Convention of
Royal Burghs had awakened to the fact that the Sumptuary Laws had been "very
prejudicial" to them.' It was turning out that what were called the luxuries
of the rich were inseparable from the comforts and necessities of the poor.
Costly things were only costly because they were much desired, and because
much was consequently given to those who could find, produce, or make them.
And a great part of this cost went of necessity to the Muscular Labour,
which was the contribution of the poor. Again, the Royal Burghs were
beginning to find out that even within their own "precincts," individual
enterprise was breaking through the incubus of their communal restrictions.
Individual citizens and Burgesses, seeing the success of their neighbours in
the "unfree " Towns, were entering into partnership with them in various
enterprises and speculations. It is worth while to listen for a moment to
the words in which this conduct of men in the free disposal of their own
faculties, and of their own property, was denounced by that spirit of
tyranny which is never more oppressive than when it is wielded in the
supposed interest of a local popular majority. "The Convention being
resolved no longer to suffer the privileges of Royal Burghs to be abused and
encroached upon by their own Burgesses, who, by joining stocks with
unfreemen, inhabitants in the Burghs of Regality and Barony, and other
unfree places, both in point of trade and shipping, whereby those unfreemen
receive all imaginable encouragement from freemen in Royal Burghs to trade,
and that the said freemen do voluntarily and with their own hands destroy
the privileges of the Royal Burghs —therefore" the Convention denounced new
pains and penalties against all such persons—as disloyal to the Community to
which they belonged.
Here was an aperture in the armour of Burghal
monopolies which the irrepressible energies of individual interests were
quite sure to widen. Partnerships could be easily concealed, and the only
result of enforcing inquisi.ion into the use to which men might put their
own money, would have been, and doubtless was, that the most enterprising
Minds would seek refuge in the new Towns. With them, therefore, the contest
was hopeless, and it soon ceased altogether. But for many years after this
date, and even after the Union, the exclusiveness of the Guilds in the
supposed interest of the Skilled Labour, and of the Retail Trade of the old
Burghs, continued unabated. It was reserved for this system as it prevailed
in Glasgow, to afford the most signal illustration of its antagonism to the
laws of Nature. The site of Glasgow had been chosen without any view to
industry even of the earliest and rudest kind. It had not clustered under a
Rock Fortress, like Stirling or Dumbarton. It had not arisen beside a
natural harbour, like Dundee or Aberdeen. It had not grown up out of a
fishing-village, like Greenock or Rothesay. Its nucleus was not even a
feudal Castle. Its position had been determined by the Cathedral of St.
Mungo, and was originally a mere hamlet of " the Bishop's men" living under
the protection of a great Archiepiscopal See. It was not among the number of
the most Ancient Royal Burghs of the Kingdom. In the Fifteenth Century its
importance was increased by being made the seat of a new University. But
this was done through the same influence and agency of the Church to which
the Town owed its own foundation. Glasgow was itself, therefore, nothing
more than one of the Burghs of Barony on a Church Estate. Two of the Old
Royal Burghs, Rutherglen and Dumbarton, long domineered over it, as now
Glasgow tried to domineer over Greenock and Paisley. It is true that it
stood near the river Clyde, towards which its houses gradually straggled.
But the Clyde at that point was distant from the sea, its course was very
shallow, and it was being perpetually silted up with shifting sandbanks.
This was one of the causes of its decay in Cromwell's time. Only through the
new openings which came with the Union did it begin to revive again. But, as
a Seaport, it never could have reached its present position without the
operation of the Steam Dredge, through which ships of the heaviest burden
have long been able to ascend the river, and to lie beside its quays. During
the last forty-six years very nearly forty millions of tons of material have
been removed from the bed of the Clyde by the Steam Dredge—a mass which
would form a conical mountain 513 feet high, with a circumference at the
base of one mile and a half.' Yet it is a memorable fact that when the
future Inventor of the new Steam Engine, without which dredging on this
gigantic scale would have been impossible, came to reside and to open a shop
in Glasgow, he was persecuted as an interloper and a poacher on the domain
of the Guild of Hammermen. James Watt was then probably known there as an
ingenious Mechanic, but he must have also been known as the grandson of one
of the earliest Bailies of the "unfree" Town of Greenock, that most
presumptuous union of the villages of the Crawfords and the Shaws. The
Hammerrnen declared that from the competition of such an "unfree-man," the
whole Community would "suffer skaith." A man on whom Nature had bestowed, in
richer measure than it had ever been bestowed before, the very individual
and the very special gift of mechanical genius, and whose discoveries were
destined to raise Glasgow to be one of the greatest Cities of the world, was
actually driven from her Burghal "precincts." Fortunately the University had
precincts of its own which were outside the "liberties "of the Guilds.
Within that sanctum this patient and laborious Mind wrought out the great
problem on which its heart, as well as its intellect, was set. It thought
and pondered, and weighed and measured, and tried and tried again, until at
last the moment of Inspiration came, and one of the most tremendous agencies
in the material world became tractable as a little child. It was tamed,
yoked, and bound to every variety of human service —an immense contribution
indeed, not only to the Common Good of Glasgow, but to the Common Good of
all Mankind.
The same natural play of instinct and of motive which
had led the Landowners with such immense success to foster individual
liberty and enterprise, in the hands of their own Villagers and Feuars, now
led them also to rely more and more on the same great principle as equally
applicable to their agricultural Tenants. For this purpose the first step to
be taken was that, wherever possible, on the expiry of old Leases, their
farms should be re-let to individual Tenants. Such Tenants became at once
freed from the trammels of Communal Usage, and could move out of the ruts in
which the wheels of progress were jammed up to the very axletrees. They
could —but were they sure to do so? Here again there was an education of
experience—analogous to that which only very slowly and very gradually
educated the Towns in the lessons of the new Industrial Age. It soon turned
out that neither the mere circumstance of undivided holdings, the additional
circumstance of very long Leases, were enough of themselves to secure an
improving Agriculture. The reason is obvious. If the sources of all Wealth
are Mind, Materials, and Opportunity, it is clearly not enough to have only
one, or only two of these sources opened. Materials are useless, and so is
Opportunity, and so are both together, if the appropriate qualities of Mind
to make use of them are wanting. Significant indications are given in the
Reports so often referred to, of the steps of experience through which the
Owners of land were taught how best to secure the improvement of the soil.
Thus in the Lennox, the perpetual tenure of Feu for a fixed annual payment,
had been given over various areas of agricultural land to men who thereby
became small Owners, and had all the inducements to improvement which
Ownership is reputed to give. But neither the accumulations due to Mind in
the past, nor those aspirations of Mind which regard the future, were
present to take due advantage of the Material and of the Opportunity. These
Feuars belonged originally to the old unimproving class. They had no
conception of educating their children for any other employment than that on
which they and their fathers had maintained existence. Consequently they
went on sub-dividing their lands among a progeny as ignorant and unimproving
as themselves. "They thought it a disgrace that their children should be
anything but Lairds." This sub-division went on increasing until the little
possessions had become so small, in 1794, that some of the Owners could not
afford to keep a horse. Then we have the usual sickening detail of constant
over-cropping, of "nothing being laid out on improvements, and of the land
being scourged to the last extremity." The whole produce could hardly
support the families that depended upon it, even with the addition of what
was procured by the unremitting labour of the wife and children in spinning
and a little weaving? This is an exact description of the results of a
similar condition of things now common among the Peasant Proprietors of
parts of France, as described by such eye-witnesses as Mr. Hamerton, Lady
Verney, and many others.
The lesson against feuing agricultural hand was hardly
needed. Land feued is land sold. Feuing is merely one form of total
alienation. A "Superior" parts with all the powers and rights of Ownership,
except that of receiving a Rent charge. The Feuar becomes the Proprietor. On
the other hand, the evidence furnished by the Report of 1794 on
Dumbartonshire, is in favour of what are now called Allotments—that is to
say, small areas of land let to Labourers and Tradesmen who were
intelligent. These were reported to be by no means ill cultivated or
unimproved.' On the contrary, they were reported to be as far advanced as
any part of the County—at a time too, when the Common Good of the Burgh was
lying comparatively waste. On such Allotments the full benefit of individual
interest was at work, coupled often with knowledge above the average of that
possessed by the old class of Tenants. Feus are an excellent tenure for
purposes of Building, and Scotchmen generally will not build on any tenure
less secure and permanent. But there is no reason which should induce a
Proprietor to give off agricultural land on this tenure. If he wishes to
sell, it is best to sell out and out. But the example of those old feus to
small Owners in Dumbartonshire is an excellent illustration of the general
principle on which all improvements depend.
There was, however, another case in which the
teachings of experience were more practically important. Leases of great
length are another panacea amongst those who have had no experience, which
is often recommended with much confidence. But this also was tried, and with
the same result, depending exactly on the same principles. It appears from
Professor Walker's Work, published in 1808, that Archibald, third Duke of
Argyll, the friend of Culloden, had been induced to give some very long
Leases of large farms in Mull—Leases for "three nineteens," or a period of
fifty-seven years. He expected the Tenants to set a pattern of industry and
improvement" on such length and security of tenure. But the expectation was
not fulfilled. When the Leases were half expired the farms were found to be
as little improved as any on the Island. The same experiment had been tried
in the Island of Islay by Mr. Campbell of Shawfield, who, in 1720, let all
his Estate on Leases of the same long duration, with the result that in 1764
that Island had undergone no improvement—with one solitary exception. Flax
had been introduced, and became a, source of industry and advantage to the
Island. But this one exception was the result, not of the long Leases, but
of the only compulsory clause which had been inserted in them by the
Proprietor, which was a clause binding the Tenants to cultivate flax.' It
thus appeared that the only one item of improvement which had been effected
during more than half a century was due, not to the Mind of the Tenant, but
to the Mind of the Proprietor— to his forethought, and to his knowledge—in
binding men who were comparatively ignorant, to begin a new industry, which
of themselves they never would have thought of.
In this one exception to the general result we see the
whole secret and the whole philosophy of the only method by which it was
then possible to improve the agriculture of Scotland—to arrest the
increasing impoverishment of her soil, and to lift her rural population out
of the poverty and sloth in which they lived. It was the exercise, in a new
direction, of the same Power to which the Parliament of Scotland had often
appealed before, not only to secure a Tenantry loyal to the Government, but
also to secure such rural improvements as were then known. Educated men were
to direct the energies of men less instructed. Mind was to keep its power
over Muscle. Very long terms of Lease, during which this power was to be
suspended, could not but be mischievous. Most fortunately for the country,
few Proprietors had been induced to try an experiment which could not be
stopped during the long period of nearly sixty years—although it might be
quite evident before one-half that time had expired, that it must end in
total failure. In the great majority of cases they had granted no other
Leases than those of the ordinary duration of "one nineteen," and at the end
of every Lease they inserted stipulations in the new Tacks binding the
Tenants to execute certain specified improvements. These, of course,
expanded with the expanding knowledge of the day. Proprietors were
themselves only in course of being educated; and some were before others in
appreciating and accepting the advancing knowledge of a new science. In some
points they were almost as slow to break with ancient Usages, and to
perceive the mischief of them, as the most ignorant of their Tenants. The
heavy dues exacted for "Thirlage," or the maintenance of Mills, were a great
evil, and they were not wholly abolished till recent years. But the
stipulations in Leases became more and more enlightened and important in
their effects. They began generally with stipulations for the making of
enclosures, and for the building of better Houses than the old hovels, which
were as universal in the Lowlands as in the Highlands. But this rudimentary
step of providing for enclosures speedily involved corresponding
stipulations for the uses to which enclosed land was to be applied. There
were clauses to forbid old habits which were ruinous. There were clauses
prescribing new methods which were fruitful—clauses forbidding continuous
cropping with Cereals—clauses enjoining an alternation with the new Green
Crops—clauses insisting on the use of Sown Grasses—and on the application of
due quantities of manure. With the growing knowledge of the cultivating
class, and the yearly proofs experienced of increasing produce and of rising
values, the necessity for such detailed stipulations gradually abated. The
"rules of good husbandry" became a legal phrase, having a definite meaning,
and susceptible of judicial interpretation. A class of Tenant farmers arose
having themselves ample knowledge, sufficient capital, and technical skill.
In proportion as the permanent accommodation and apparatus required for
scientific agriculture became more costly, it became more and more the
universal habit in Scotland that the Owner should supply that accomrnodation
and apparatus along with the land itself. In some cases part of this work
was done by the Tenant on stipulated conditions—he making his own
calculations for repayment, either by comparative lowness of rent, or by
comparative length of Lease—or by both combined.
It is not often that we can enjoy in human affairs the
sharp and clear processes of demonstration which are the glorious reward of
Physical Research. Yet such—and not less certain—are the proofs now afforded
by the history of Scotland in favour of the Powers and Agencies through
which her Agriculture was reformed during the latter half of the Eighteenth
Century. By all that had happened before the change—by all that ceased to
happen wherever it was effected—by all that continued to happen wherever it
was hampered or delayed,—it is proved to demonstration that terrible evils
and dangers were inseparably bound up with the older system, and with the
ignorant habits in which the whole of it consisted. This is one kind of
proof. But there is another kind. By all the benefits which the change
immediately conferred—by all the increase in these benefits which arose in
proportion as it became developed—by all the sacrifice of them wherever it
was still delayed,—we can see without the shadow of a doubt, that the new
system was founded on Natural Laws, on the recognition which they demand,
and on the obedience which they reward. Nature takes no cognisance of
stupidity in the sense of allowance or of remission. She does take
cognisance of it in the way of punishment. Chronic poverty and frequent
famines had been, as we have seen, the punishment in Scotland of the
ignorant wastefulness of its traditionary agricultural customs. So now when
Mind had been awakened, and when its energies, wielded by individual men,
had been turned with better knowledge to the improvement of the soil, Nature
took notice of it by a lavish increase of her fruits. It is a striking fact
that the "iii years "—the bad seasons—of 1781-2 were the last which
afflicted any large part of Scotland with severe distress and the danger of
famine. In those years the new knowledge, and the new class of Tenants who
were able to make any use of it, were as yet established only in some parts
of the country. Everywhere else the old usages were still supreme—the Runrig
cultivation—the promiscuous grazing—the wretched Cattle—the not less
wretched Oats and Bear. The consequence was that over no less than fifteen
of the Counties of Scotland, a population of not less than 111,521 souls
were only rescued from starvation by charitable collections.' After this
date down to our own times there have been bad seasons again and again
recurring at about the usual intervals—but never have they had the same
effect—except in the few remaining fastnesses of the ancient ignorance.
These fastnesses have chiefly been in the Hebrides, and in a few Districts
of the Northern Highlands —always where, only where, and in proportion as,
the old stupidities have resisted and survived.
But the story of this resistance is so curious and so
instructive that it must be shortly told.
We have seen how in 1739, under the advice of
Culloden, the first great step had been taken on the Hebridean Estates of
the Argyll family—that of redeeming the class of Sub-Tenants from their
servitudes to the Tacksmen under whom they universally held at Will. In some
cases they were themselves raised to the position of Tacksrnen—in all cases
they were freed from indefinite exactions. We have seen, too, how shocked
Culloden had been by the wasteful and barbarous husbandry he witnessed in
Tyree. But on the other hand he did not see his way to any immediate or
compulsory change in these methods of cultivation. He probably thought that
self-interest, now called into play under new conditions of security, would
be enough to bring about reform. Wielding the powers of Ownership, he had
abolished one deeply-rooted and most ancient custom—the custom of indefinite
Servitudes. He did not know, or perfectly understand, that nothing but the
same powers, wielded with like determination and like intelligence, could
uproot those other Servitudes—as old and as destructive —under which the
people were chained and bound amongst each other in a perfect tangle of
obstructive usages.
Culloden and all that generation passed away, with his
two friends, Duke John and Duke Archibald (Lord Islay). The struggle was
unceasing to get the people to amend their culture. Then came the
Potato—then the Kelp. Subsistence became comparatively easy, and was
sometimes abundant. But all this came to a people unprepared by previous
habits, or by any new aspirations, to profit by it. Nothing was saved or
stored. They lived, and ate, and multiplied. From the date of my
Grandfather's succession in 1770, he issued ceaseless instructions for the
improvement of the people. He insisted in his Leases on enclosures, to save
the arable lands from constant invasion by whole herds of useless horses and
lean cattle. He insisted on better Houses. He tried his best to prevent the
systematic waste of Barley by illicit distillation. He tried to establish
Fisheries, lie tried to stop the destructive habit of breaking up pasture on
Sands which were liable to be blown. When Kelp became an important resource
he left so large a part of it to the workers that they held their land
practically for nothing, because the whole rent, and often much more, came
out of Kelp. His rent from 13,000 acres of land did not amount to more than
the saleable value of the Barley crop alone. All other produce,—potatoes,
lint, sheep, milk, butter and cheese, poultry, eggs, etc., were not counted
at all as contributing to rent, because the Proprietor said "he wished the
Tenants to live plentifully and happily." It was all in vain—as regards any
permanent improvement. Plenty is a relative term. Produce which was
plenteous for a population of 1676 persons in 1769, would not be plenteous
to a population which had risen to 2776 in 1802. In that year the condition
of the Island alarmed his agent, Mr. Maxwell of Aros, an excellent and able
man who was maternal grandfather of the late Dr. Norman Macleod. His Report
is a repetition of the worst accounts to the Board of Agriculture in 1794.
Subdivision had reduced the holdings to starvation point. The Cows did not
produce calves above once in two or three years. Troops of Horses, used only
for dragging seaweed at one time of the year, preyed all the rest of the
year on the exhausted pastures. Hosts of Cottars living only on the wages of
Kelp- burning oppressed the unfortunate Tenants. The quality of the Barley
was deteriorating rapidly. Ignorance of all husbandry, and stubborn
attachment to the old customs, offered "arduous obstacles to the improvement
of the Island." The additional One Thousand people who had grown up in
recent years could not be supported. Iy Grandfather had begun to entertain
the proposal to help them to the Colonies. But in 1803 there arose, as we
have seen, that panic against Emigration described before. The old Duke
seems to have deeply shared in it. His soldierly spirit was stirred, too, in
favour of the men who had enlisted in the Fencible Regiments which were
about to be disbanded at the Peace. He determined to try a new plan. He
resolved to break down and cut up several of the larger Farms falling out of
Lease, and to settle as many of the people as he could on smaller but
separate Holdings of a size calculated to support a Family with ease. But
one essential part of this scheme was enclosure —individual possession—the
abolition of promiscuous waste in the form of Runrig. He employed a
professional Surveyor to lay out the, new "Crofts," which were to be capable
of supporting not less than 16 Cows.
This most benevolent scheme was met by the most
obstinate resistance on the part of the people. Rather than give up the
wasteful habits of Runrig, they declared they would rather go to join the
emigration which Lord Selkirk was then leading to North America. The Duke's
agent at the time was a Highlander himself, intimate with the condition and
habits of the people. Yet he writes almost in despair with their infatuated
blindness to their own obvious interests, and to the value of the reforms
which had by that time become accepted by every educated man. He suggested
to the Duke a postponement of the plan. Yet time was needed to make even a
beginning, and the powers of Ownership were once more asserted to insist on
the abolition of a system so destructive and so dangerous. By firmness, and
by assistance given in fencing, the division and individuality of the arable
lands was at last effected. The grazings only continued to be used in
common, but even on these the amount of stock was carefully fixed and
apportioned to each man.
Now followed a most remarkable series of facts. The
old Field-Marshal died in 1806. In one respect his policy was entirely
successful. The separation of holdings—the individualisation of the arable
areas—resulted, almost automatically, in a great increase of produce. But it
had another result which was not foreseen. It facilitated and gave a new
impulse to further subdivision. Under the Runrig system the introduction of
an additional shareholder required assent. In settling this there were at
least some difficulties to be overcome in the way of subdivision. Under
separate holdings of the arable area these difficulties were much
diminished. Increasing produce and a greater freedom in subdividing, were at
once taken advantage of by a people whose intelligence was not developed in
proportion to its opportunities. Nothing but the continued exercise of the
powers of Ownership in fighting a watchful and uphill battle against
inveterate habits, could have been successful. Instead of this there was an
almost complete abandonment of all control. There came a Reign— not of Law,
or of Mind—but of what in medical language is called "Amentia." My
Grandfather's Successor' lived for thirty-three years—during the whole of
which time the powers of Ownership may be said to have been suspended. He
was a perfect type of the kind of Landowner who was adored in Ireland—one
who never meddled or interfered with the stupidities of Custom. Celtic
usages were allowed their course. Subdivision went on at a redoubled rate,
and population kept up even more than pace. In 1822 the Farms which had been
held by small Tenants ever since Culloden's time were crowded with a
population of 2869 souls; whilst the newly divided farms, five in number,
held no less than 1080 more. There had been a bad season in 1821. The Cattle
were almost starved, and there were many cases of great misery among the
people. Once more, Kelp came to the rescue. There was an extraordinary
supply of it, and this, with wholesale insolvency admitted and allowed,
tided over the crisis for a time. Next came another tremendous blow. The
whole Kelp Trade rested on Fiscal Protection, and on two special taxes
alone. One was upon Spanish Baril la—a Plant growing not in the sea, but on
the land, and rich in the Alkalis which seaweed afforded. The other impost
was the tax on Salt—a tax most oppressive to numberless industries, and
specially injurious to the Highlands, through the impediments thrown in the
way of the trade in fish. From common salt, which is a salt of Soda, the
same important Alkali could be made into other combinations. Both these
taxes were repealed—one in 1823, the other in 1826. The trade of the Kingdom
as a whole was immensely benefited. But the special, and the only
manufacture of the Hebrides, and of the adjacent coasts, was destroyed.
In all other countries when Mines are exhausted, or
when Mills are closed, or when any other local industry is extinguished, the
people who had been so employed invariably move off to other fields where
their labour can be made remunerative to themselves, and useful to the
world. But the Hebrideans never thought of this. There is, nevertheless, no
suspension of the laws of Nature for the special and exclusive protection of
any particular set of men, merely because they belong to a particular race,
or because they live in an Island, or because they speak a particular
language. Failing the Kelp trade, they still held on by the Potato. The
consequence was that the "ill years," which must every now and then recur,
always smote them with the misery and famine which had in former generations
smitten the rest of Scotland. In 1836-7 there was terrible misery all over
the Highlands wherever the old system still survived, and especially in
Skye. We have an account of it, and of the causes which produced it, from an
educated Highlander, who writes with that high intelligence of his race
which never fails to be conspicuous where-ever Highlanders are lifted above
the level of the old Paternal Customs. I need not repeat his story. It is a
mere duplicate of the course of events which we have followed in Tyree.
Everything that had been done in the panic of 1803 against emigration, had
simply ended in aggravating the evil. Even the making of the Caledonian
Canal, begun in the same year, from which much was hoped, had done no
permanent good. The Skye men had indeed worked at it. Whilst the
construction of it had lasted, between 300 and 400 of them had earned from
£3500 to £4000 in the half-year. But there was no change of habits—no
elevation in the standard of living. On the contrary, it was becoming lower
and lower from the wretched husbandry, and from the stimulated growth of
population. The one Parish of Kilmuir had in 1736 only 1230 souls. Even this
was far above the population it had supported in the Epoch of the Clans.
This is repeatedly and emphatically stated by Mr. Macgregor, and it reminds
us that even then the population of the old Military Ages had been far
exceeded. Yet nineteen years later, the population had risen to 1572. In
1791 it was 2060. In 1831 it was 3415, and in this year of renewed famine
1836-7, it amounted to about 4000.
It will be observed that this exorbitant increase went
on after the Kelp trade had been destroyed. There was nothing whatever to
justify, or account for such increase except an ever- increasing dependence
on the Potato, and a corresponding lowering of the conditions of life. There
vas not the slightest advance in agricultural knowledge or industry. On the
contrary —no account given by wandering Englishmen or by Low Countrymen,
which may be thought highly coloured by anti-Celtic prejudices, can exceed
in wretchedness the account by this descendant of the Clan Gregor in respect
to the industrial habits of the Skyemen among whom he lived so late as 1838.
The women alone did all the harrowing; whilst every implement and every
method of cultivation were alike barbarous and ineffective. Next came the
final blow—the Potato disease of 1846. By that time the population of Tyree
had increased to about 5000 souls—an increase probably without parallel in
any purely rural district in the world. It may bring this abnormal
multiplication more strikingly home to us, when we observe the fact that
this single Hebridean Island added to its population, during about 80 years
a greater number of souls than were added to the population of the Cathedral
City of Glasgow during all the generations which elapsed between the War of
Independence and the Reformation.' It did this under the stimulus of a
manufacture which rested wholly on Protective Duties injurious to the rest
of the community—under the influence of a mindless contentment with a very
low diet—and of an indulgence, not less mindless, in instincts which are
natural in themselves, but which, like all other natural instincts, require
the control of an enlightened Will. The love of offspring is a natural
instinct which we share with all creatures. But educated men do not anywhere
encourage their children to build hovels round their home, without reference
to adequate means of maintaining a civilised existence. Even among the Birds
of the Air, and the creatures of the Field, there is a wonderful, and even a
mysterious law by which a wholesome dispersion is secured, and limited areas
of subsistence are kept from being overstocked. It is a curious fact, quite
common in the Highlands, that small areas of arable land which can never be
enlarged from the nature of the country, are frequented by a single pair of
Partridges, producing a single covey every year, which, even when never
shot, never remain to multiply. It is true that Man has powers and resources
which the lower animals have not. It is true that with every new mouth that
is born, two new hands are born to feed it. But it is not true that the two
hands have power in all circumstances to earn new subsistence. Sustenance
cannot be sensibly increased upon St. Kilda. Nature intervenes and kills off
the children by a horrible and mysterious disease. Even those that remain
live largely upon charity; and are now said to exhibit the moral
deterioration which such dependence always causes, when it becomes habitual.
This is an extreme case. But it is very little more extreme than the case of
other Hebridean Islands. The love of Race is another natural instinct. But
educated men do not cling to spots of birth when wider regions invite to
wider duties, and to more fruitful works.
Sooner or later Nature finds out the sins and
blindnesses of all her children. We know what were the results of the Potato
famine in Ireland, where it fell on a population which had never been
redeemed from a terrible continuity of Celtic usages, and had never enjoyed
the opportunities afforded to the people of Tyree, by the abolition of
Middlemen, by the formation of separate holdings, and by rents kept down to
a low rate on purpose to let them live with exceptional ease. The same
effects resulted where all these opportunities had been afforded, but where
they had not been put to the right use by minds adequately prepared. There
was imminent danger of starvation. It was prevented by charity—the charity
of Proprietors generously aided by the charity of the Public. This charity
was rendered effective in the Hebrides by the comparatively limited area of
distress. The rest of Scotland suffered great losses in one article of
produce and of sale. But no part of Scotland suffered any danger of famine,
except those parts of it where the old mediaeval ignorances had been
suffered to survive. There never was so clear a lesson. Conviction was
forced on the poor people of the island of Tyree, and they addressed to Sir
John M'Neill, who was then at the head of the Board of Supervision for the
Poor, an earnest and even a passionate petition asking for assistance to
emigrate to Canada. I have nowhere seen a more forcible and more conclusive
plea set forth in favour of this remedy.' It fell to the lot of my Father
and myself to respond to it. At great cost we enabled upwards of a thousand
people to go where they could put to use the admirable elements of character
which never fail to be exhibited by Highlanders when they move out into the
stream of the world's progress. When I visited Canada and the United States
in 1879, I had the warmest invitations from Highlanders who had emigrated;
and the accounts of success were universal,
I take but little merit to myself, that in the face of
proofs so ample, and of results so terrible, I determined—with due regard to
local circumstances, and to a past which could not be too suddenly reversed
without hardship—to return to the principles which—starting everywhere from
the same conditions—had secured the wealth, the comfort, and the
civilisation of the rest of Scotland. Subdivision was stopped. Existing
subdivisions, when vacant from death, insolvency, or migrations, were never
put up to competition, as they would have been under Middlemen. They were
invariably added to the holding of the nearest neighbours who could take
them. Some new Tenants from the Low Country were brought in, who could show
new methods, and introduce some circulation of ideas into a stagnant air.
By, the steady prosecution of this process during forty years, some approach
has been gradually made to the condition of things which was aimed at by the
old Field-Marshal. With the increasing size of holdings, comfort and
prosperity have steadily advanced. But the tendency to revert to ancient
habits reappears from time to time; and the encouragements of a very
ignorant sentiment " out of doors" has lately led to an attempt to go back
through the paths of violence to the ruinous practices of the past, in spite
of all reason, and in spite of a long and a terrible experience.
I have spoken of the wonder that must often strike us
when we look back on the slowness of Mankind in opening their eyes to the
most obvious facts of nature, and to conclusions of the reason which now
appear to us quite as obvious as the facts. There is one signal example of
this connected with the history of a large part of Scotland, which applies
not to the poorer, but to the more educated classes, and especially to the
Landowners. An immense area of the Western and Northern Highlands is
occupied by high and very steep mountains. We have seen that only little
bits of them were ever put to any use at all under the old system, and even
those bits were used for only about six weeks in the year. For several
generations it had been known in the Border Highlands that such mountains
were most valuable grazings for sheep, which could be fed in thousands upon
their steepest surfaces, and could remain on them all the year round. Yet it
was only very slowly and very late that it dawned upon Farmers, or upon
Landowners, that the Highland mountains could be put to the same use, and
could be thus redeemed from all but absolute waste. The enormous addition
made by this discovery to the natural produce of the country, is very apt to
be forgotten now, because of the great ignorance prevalent on the extent of
area which was thus, for the first time, made contributory to the comforts
and sustenance of mankind. On my own estate there is one Mountain which,
with its spurs and peaks and shoulders, occupies more than 20,000 acres. Of
this great area only about 500 acres are arable, and many of these have been
reclaimed and enclosed at great cost, within the last fifty years. Of the
rest, probably not more than 1000 acres would be available for Cattle. All
the remainder, at least 18,500 acres, are very steep, and many of them
either actually, or almost, precipitous. No other animal except Sheep could,
or ever did, consume the grasses which clothe these surfaces more or less
abundantly. Yet they can and do feed some 8700 Sheep, without inter fering
with the comparatively few Cattle which were ever reared in the olden time.
If, now, we look at an Orographical Map of the Highlands, we shall find that
this case is the typical case of the Western Highlands and of the Northern
Highlands, embracing the larger half of the Counties of Inverness, Ross, and
Sutherland. Sir John Sinclair calculated that before the introduction of
sheep-farming, the whole produce exported from all the Highlands did not
exceed £300,000 worth of very lean and poor Cattle. Tinder Cheviot Sheep he
shows that the same area would produce at least twice the value of mutton,
or £600,000, besides all the Wool, equal to a further sum of £900,000. This
Wool, again, when manufactured, would represent a value of at least
£3,600,000 of Woollens. The total difference therefore between the produce
of the Country, under the new system as compared with the old, was as the
difference between £600,000, and £4,200,000—this difference being all added
to the comfort and resources of Mankind.
It does seem almost incredible that Highland
Landowners and Tenants should have been so slow to find out an application
and a use for the Moors and Mountains they occupied or possessed, a use
which in reality constituted as much the addition of a new country as the
recovery of the Bedford Level from the Sea. The Mountains round Moffat in
Dumfriesshire are hardly less steep or less high than the Mountains round
Loch Maree in Ross-shire, or round Loch Laxford in Sutherland. The Highland
Mountains had even an advantage over the Border Mountains, that they were
nearer to the Gulf Stream, and snow lay less long upon them. Yet the
stupidities of Custom and Tradition were so difficult of removal that
Sheep-farming spread as slowly as the Potato, or the manufacture of Kelp. No
doubt the new Sheep-farming involved some local displacement of population,
because Sheep could not be supported without access to low ground, which was
sometimes occupied by "Clachans," liable to periodical distress and famine.
But this displacement of population was far less than that which had been
involved all over the Low Country by the abandonment of Runrig, and in the
Border Counties by the Sheep-farming which had superseded the Moss-troopers.
Neither again did it involve necessarily in all cases very large farms. The
Highland Counties have at this moment a much greater variety of holdings in
respect to size, than the most thriving Lowland Counties. Neither again did
it involve any general substitution of Lowland farmers for Highlanders. Some
of the earliest sheep-farmers were Highlanders who had acquired capital by
industry. Others were Lowlanders who brought knowledge of management, and
imparted it, to the immense advantage of the country. It remains therefore a
wonderful example of the slow progress of new ideas that the Highland
Proprietors adopted Sheep-farming on the hills so slowly and so late as they
actually did. Although it began as soon as 1768, it was not universally
applied to the wasted areas till as late as 1823.
But there is another phenomenon, even more wonderful,
which is equally common—and that is, the coming back of old blindnesses—the
revival of old errors—and even the passionate return to practices which
Nature has condemned. Yet this phenomenon has its analogue in the material
world as well as in the World of Mind. It is now universally admitted that
Development, or Evolution, does not always work in one direction. It works
downwards as well as upwards. As Tennyson expresses it—"Thronèd races may
degrade."' There is even reason to believe in a constant force tending to
revert to earlier and ruder stages of existence. Whether this be so or not,
the fact is certain that there are many creatures that fall from a
comparatively high, to a comparatively low, organisation. The freedom—nay
the very organs—of locomotion are abandoned and cast away. Even the noble
faculty of vision is lost. The creature becomes fixed to a bit of rock, or
to the shells and exuvie of dead things. So it is with Man. At the beginning
of this Work I have referred to the influence exerted over our longings and
desires by the pressure of modern life—the "fuinum strepitumque Rom"—the
strain of Work in the pursuit of Wealth—or the not less trying strain of
Mind in a speculative age in the quest of satisfying Truth. All this tends
to throw a most false glamour on the ages which have passed. The old tastes
for a Wild Life return upon us, in- herited through many generations.
Most of us know the feeling. It is pleasant to return
to childhood, and the pleasures of imagination. I never read any detailed
account of so-called "primitive" life in any of the happier climates of the
world, without at least some passing feelings of desire to join in its
freedom and pursuits—to live in Pile Dwellings on the lagoons of a Coral
Sea, or in huts on the tops of trees—to watch the Birds of Paradise in the
Forests of New Guinea—to shoot reedy arrows at the great Ground Pigeon—or to
hunt for the wondrous hatching-mounds of the Brush Turkey. Not less
attractive to other tastes would it be to go back to the Epoch of the
Clans,— to sail, and to fight, and to spoil in beautiful Galleys, with all
their bravery of war. It is perhaps less easy for civilised men to think
with any envy of the old Celtic habits—of the wattled huts, jointly
inhabited with the cows and calves—of the perpetual atmosphere of
Peat-reek—of all the hardest labour left to women, and of seeing them yoked
to Harrows as described by Mr. Macgregor, writing as late as 1838. But
imagination has a wonderful power of winnowing out all facts that are
disagreeable, and of resting only on those which have a flavour of the
picturesque. We have seen that not only the charm and glamour of these old
habits, but the actual delight of exercising the powers of" Chiefery" with
which they were inseparably connected, had been strong enough to corrupt the
noble chivalry of Norman Barons, so that even a man near in blood to Robert
the Bruce had descended to the level of a mere "Wolf of Badenoch." We have
seen how, in a much later day, another conspicuous example of the same
influence had been displayed by Sir James Macdonald, who was known in the
Palaces of the Kingdom as a most polished and accomplished Knight—but who,
when he returned to Islay or Kintyre, became the bloody and the fierce
1iIacsorlie. In our own time it has too often an influence not indeed so
formidable in action, but hardly less corrupting in opinion. Harmless in the
form of mere sentiment and poetry, it ceases to be harmless when it perverts
History and loosens the hold of Mind over the rights and obligations upon
which every Society must be built.
In this form it acts as a solvent upon Opinion which
is the root of Law. It subordinates the Reason to Fancy—it elevates the
ignorant Declamation of the Platform over the responsible decisions of the
Bench. This is a return to the power of "Chiefery" not in its ancient and
nobler form but in a new and debased embodiment. It is a reversion, as
Darwin expresses it, in Biology, to an old and ruder type. It is however
worse than this. It is a mere travesty and corruption of that violence
against which the Monarchy and the civilisation of Scotland had to wage for
centuries one long continuous war. It is the true modern analogue of the
worst Anarchy of the Clans.
It is curious to observe the different direction which
this kind of sentiment has taken in regard to the country formerly inhabited
by the Border Clans. That country has been infinitely more changed and more
depopulated than the Celtic Highlands. The vast stretches of moorland, and
the long vista of vacant Glens which strike the eye on the borders of
Dumfriesshire and the Upper Wards of Lanarkshire, are far more desolate of
human habitation than any similar areas in the Highlands possessing equal
possibilities of reclamation. But more than this: the greener and lower
Valleys which are so beautiful in Selkirk and Roxburgh, are almost entirely
destitute of the smaller Holdings which are abundant and successful all over
the Counties of Argyll and Inverness. How does true Poetic Sentiment deal
with the memory of the days when these Valleys were full of a military
population—when a few powerful Chiefs could summon at the shortest notice
armies of 10,000 men? It sings of those days indeed. But the Singer does not
pretend to wish that they should return. Let us listen for a moment to the
melodious words in which the great Minstrel of the Borders recalled the
Military Ages of that pas- toral land in which, when a child, he lifted
his little hands to the lightning in a raging Thunderstorm,' and shouted
with excitement "Bonny, bonny!":-
"Sweet Teviot! On thy silver tide The glaring
bale-fires blaze no more: No longer steel-clad warriors ride Along
thy wild and willowed shore; Where'er thou wind'st, by dale or hill,
All, all is peaceful, all is still, As if thy waves, since Time was born,
Since first they rolled upon the Tweed, Had only heard the
shepherd's reed, Nor started at the bugle-horn."
This is delightful and legitimate. But more than this
would be childish. Scott himself became a Landowner in that very country—and
latterly he possessed no inconsiderable Estate. He built a Baronial Hall.
But he did not restore a Cottier Tenantry. He enclosed and planted. But he
planted Larches. He did not invite the Workmen making high wages in Hawick
or Galashiels to come back to starve on patches of corn and of potatoes
along the once populous "Haughs" of Tweed. The unreality on which much of
this kind of sentiment is founded was never more curiously illustrated than
when the Government chose as the Head of a Commission appointed to inquire
into the Small Tenants of the North and West, a Scotch Peer' whose own
Estate is situated among the long "cleared" sheep pastures of the Southern
Highlands, and in a locality which is specially described by Sir Walter
Scott in Marinion as a perfect picture of solitude and depopulation.' This
distinguished Scotchman has given elaborate advice to Highland Proprietors
for the extension—not merely of small Holdings —but of the special form of
these which is least advantageous—that of Joint or- Township Farms. There is
nevertheless not the slightest reason to believe that he himself or any of
his brethren, would consent to cut up any portion of their great sheep
grazings, or of their comfortable and single arable Farms, for the purpose
of restoring the population of the Military Ages. Many Owners in the Lowland
Counties now wish that they had, as the Highland Counties have, more small
Farms, and fewer of the largest class. But no man who knows anything of
Agriculture, or of the influences which promote its progress, would ever
recommend the revival of the old Township System. In my own experience I
have always found that the moment any "Crofter" becomes exceptionally
industrious and exceptionally prosperous, he earnestly desires, above all
things, that his grazings as well as his arable land, should be fenced off
from those of his neighbours, so that he may have the exclusive use of his
own faculties in the better tillage of his ]and and in the better breeding
of his stock. The multiplication of small Farms, indeed, such as will
profitably employ the whole industry and capital of individual men, is an
object most desirable. But the conditions of success vary with every
locality, and can only be determined by local knowledge. It cannot be
settled by a vague desire to revive the usages of a time which has passed
away for ever.
Sentiment, however, must never be surrendered to those
who have little knowledge and no balance. Such are the men who are very apt
to claim it as their own, whilst instructed men are too apt to leave it in
their hands. Sentiment can be strong as well as weak—healthy as well as
sickly, manly as well as mawkish. It can fix its enthusiasms on what is
really good, as it too often does on what is only picturesquely bad. The
cruelties, treacheries, disloyalties, and brutalities of the Clans were mere
developments of corruption, due to the divorce between them and all settled
Government and Law. They represented nothing but anarchy in their relations
with the Nation and the Kingdom, and nothing better in their relations with
each other. But the root and the principle of their organisation was that of
a Military Tribe, recruiting from all directions,—practising obedience,—
acknowledging authority,—and loving its hereditary transmission from those
who had first afforded guidance, conduct, and protection. This is a
constructive, and not a destructive or anarchic principle. It needed only,
to be turned in a right direction to become one of the steadiest of all
foundation-stones for the building up of a great structure in the light and
air of a higher civilisation. It was thus that in the transition between the
two Ages, the broken fragments of a hundred Septs enlisted under the Banner
of the Black Watch, and began the immortal services of the Highland
Regiments. Yet this is only a late and picturesque incident in a long series
of events. Nothing is more striking or more poetic in the history of
Scotland than the slow and arduous processes by which the rough energy of
the Military Ages was transformed under the ages of industry and of peace.
Malcolm Canmore had begun the transformation by his own Union with the
Daughter of another blood. Robert the Bruce continued it by the welding of
broken Races in the heat and fire of Battle. Between the War of Independence
and the Union of the Crowns it was one long, continuous, constant, struggle.
But by slow and steady steps the work was done, and Scotland became a Nation
with a noble and a settled Jurisprudence. Our Kings became our only Chiefs:
our Country became our only Clan. Her Law, the best symbol of her History,
and the best expression of her Mind, became the only authority to which we
bowed, and the only protection to which we trusted. Under its shelter man
could have confidence in man, because there was no fear of that which even
the old Celts ranked with Pestilence and Famine—the breaking of the Bonds of
Covenant. In this high field of Human Energy,—the establishment of that
confidence in Law which is the nearest approach we can ever make to the
methods of the Divine Government,—Scotland may well be proud of the old
beginnings, and of the steady growth, of all her National Institutions.
Among these Institutions there is one of purely native
origin which, perhaps, as much as any other, is a striking embodiment of
this principle, and a splendid illustration of its effects. I refer to her
Banking system. Barter, as we all know, is the earliest form of Exchange,
and under that system if the Seller can bring his produce to a market, and
the Buyer can carry it away in safety, no higher kind of security is
required.. Then comes Money as an abstract representative of Value,
immensely facilitating Exchange, by providing an article with which, and for
which, everything can be got from somebody. Lastly comes Credit, the highest
and the most powerful of all agencies for promoting the intercourse of men.
It is the highest because it is most purely the work of Mind—the most
absolute expression of confidence in the universal authority of Law. In
other countries the intervention of the State has been required to establish
Banks, and the work assigned to them has been lauded as among the highest
efforts of Statesmanship. In Scotland an immense network of Institutions for
the universal diffusion and organisation of Credit, has been spread, as it
were, by a natural growth indigenous to the soil. In Scotland there is a
Bank for about every 4000 souls of the total population. Ten of them
represent a paid-up capital of above Nine Millions sterling, and Deposits to
the amount of more than Eighty Millions; their Branches are all over the
country. Thus everywhere men are able to take advantage, not only of their
savings, but of the credit in which they stand for their character in
business—that is for their honesty, their industry, and for all the mental
aptitudes which give promise of success. The whole of this vast system of
Credit is founded upon confidence in the Law—constituting a Wages Fund
co-extensive with the possibilities of Industry and of Knowledge. It would
all crumble at the touch of Anarchy. Under the confidence which this Reign
of Law ensures, Mind in all its forms, whether of enterprise, or of
invention, or of organisation, or only of patient perseverance, has made an
entirely new world of Scotland. It has reclaimed her soil, it has deepened
her rivers, it has built her. commercial navies, it has brought into her
harbours the products of the most distant regions, and it has redeemed her
own people, immensely multiplied, from chronic poverty and frequent famines.
There must be something wrong with ourselves, and not
with the Order of Nature, or with the Designs of Providence, if we can find
none of the pleasures of the Imagination, and none of the gratifications of
Sentiment, in changes such as these. Nothing can be more certain than that
we are but accomplishing part at least, and an essential part, of our
mission in the world when we turn the desert into the fruitful field.
Nothing can be more certain than that it is our duty to put our Talents out
to Use, and not to hide them in a napkin. Most of these Talents have their
poetic side. Slothfulness is not one of the Christian virtues, even when it
is passed amidst picturesque surroundings. The Hebrew People were not devoid
of Poetry or of Sentiment, and yet their Songs and their Prophecies are full
of the imagery derived from the improvement of the soil, as well as of the
precious and beautiful things which were brought in Commerce by the ships of
Tarshish. With them the Olive, and especially the Vine, were the symbols of
cultivated fertility; and in connection with the Vineyard, in particular, we
have the most touching and passionate allusions to all the care and labour
bestowed upon Enclosures as the best type and symbol of the work needed in
the higher cultivation of the soul. The "fencing" of land, and the
"gathering out the stones thereof," and the "planting" of it, and the
building "in the midst of it," are as apposite a description of the work of
Reclamation in Scotland as it was of the same work in Palestine. The taking
away the "Hedge thereof," and the "breaking down the wall thereof" are used
as the best Images of utter Desolation,' whilst the ravages of the wild
creatures which fences are intended to exclude are similarly used to typify
the invasions of the sacred fields by the arms of Heathendom.' There is too,
in the Book of Proverbs, a striking description of the ignorant and lazy
habits which had afflicted Scotland: "I went by the field of the slothful,
and by the vineyard of the man void of understanding; and, lo, it was all
grown over with thorns, and nettles had covered the face thereof, and the
stone wall thereof had been broken down. Then I saw, and considered it well:
I looked upon it, and received instruction. Yet a little sleep, a little
slumber, a little folding of the hands to sleep : so shall thy poverty come
as one that travelleth; and thy want as an armed man."' Yet, beyond all
question, the "pruned vine" is a much less picturesque object than the
Briers and the Thorns which ignorance or violence may allow to choke it. On
the other hand, the clustered grapes,—and the winds passing over fields of
corn,—and the flocks browsing in perspective upon great plains,—and the
sheep herded on the mountains—are all pictures full of poetry—far higher
than that which circles round the deeds and the pursuits of half-barbarian
Man.
We cannot go back to the Primitive Ages, whatever else
we do. We must live in our own time, and we must put to culture and to use,
such talents as come to us from the inheritance of the Past, and from the
opportunities of the Present. It is a delusion to suppose that the sin of
covetousness belongs specially to the later ages of the world. The naked
Savage covets more of his beads, or of his bits of iron, as much as the
civilised Man covets some new indulgence. Modern Industry has its own
dangers, and its own evils, but the truth is that the pursuit of Wealth
under the conditions of civilisation, having in it more of Mind than the
same pursuit under conditions of Barbarism, tends to be better and higher in
its moral character. There is less in the mere getting, and more in the
intellectual interest belonging to the processes through which the getting
comes. The Machine Maker thinks as much of the perfection and accuracy of
his work, as of the price he gets for it. The Shipbuilder thinks most of the
fine "lines"—of the speed, and capacity, and strength of his ships. The
Skilled Workman rejoices in his manual dexterity, and takes a pleasure,
purely intellectual, in the triumph of his hands—in the straightness of his
furrow - in his mastery over some difficult and intractable material. One of
my earliest recollections is of the laborious and conscientious pains
bestowed by my Father, as a Mechanic, on the high finish of the articles he
produced—on the perfect symmetry of form—on the joinings which the finest
touch could not detect —on the harmonies of colour and of substance.
Throughout all the Kingdom of Labour—using that word, not in its vulgar' but
in its highest meaning, as including above all the Labour of the Brain—there
is a Hierarchy or Gradation of rank corresponding to the degree in which the
mere getting of Value is subordinate, and the production of excellence is
predominant. The lowest rank must be assigned to the most purely mechanical—
such as Commission Agencies—in which there is no skill, although the work
may be useful, or even necessary, as part of the machinery of Distribution.
And most assuredly in this Hierarchy of Labour the
work of the Improver and Reclaimer of Land stands very high in the variety
and dignity of the motives which come before the mere love of gain. Time may
be on his side, but generally it is time belonging to a somewhat distant
future. A single successful voyage, one single turn of the market, may make
and has often made the fortune of a Merchant. One happy thought flashing on
the Brain of the Inventor, may reward him at a stroke with abundant wealth.
But the fruits of the Earth cannot generally be multiplied so quickly, and
we see by the history and experience of the past, how difficult it has been
to exercise the foresight, and to submit to the immediate sacrifices, which
the laborious steps of a reformed Husbandry have demanded of those who live
by it. The love of Agriculture is among the original instincts of our
nature—as distinct from others as, in early ages, is the love of the Chase,
or, in all ages, the love of Decoration. And amongst these original
instincts it is unquestionably the highest and the best, both from the
simplicity of its character and from the beneficence of its effects. With
advancing education it suffers no decay. On the contrary, it charms and
elevates the mind in proportion as it exercises us in our great commission
over Nature, and brings us into closer contact with those "abodes where
self-disturbance hath no part." The sentiment which prefers to these
attractions the far-off echoes of the Spear and Shield, or the alternating
indulgence of fierce activity and of selfish idleness, is a sentiment
unworthy alike of true Poetry, of true Religion, and of true Philosophy.
I have spoken of the natural causes which lead to
forgetfulness of the work of Ownership in the Agricultural Improver—causes
connected with the very completeness of that work, and with the total
obliteration of the older surfaces which have been reclaimed. These are
causes which lie in mere ignorance and want of thought. But, strange to say,
this ignorance or forgetfulness has been stereotyped, and as it were
enshrined, in doctrines which profess to be scientific. In this matter the
Formula-- of Political Economists have been even more feeble than in the
definitions of Wealth and of its Sources. Ricardo's famous definition of
Rent is a perfect example of that delight which men are apt to have in
formal propositions spun out of their own brains, which have little or no
correspondence with the facts of Nature. Abstract ideas are the high
prerogative of Man, and he could not get on for a single day without them.
All Language is built upon them, and the rudest Savage who can convey
intelligence to his fellow is exercising the same power which may one day
lead on his descendants to the peaks of science. Men practised Logic before
the days of Aristotle, and the Inductive Philosophy before the days of
Bacon. Political Economists are quite right to reduce within the terms of
some abstract definition, if they can, those facts of human history and the
nature of human transactions, which are the sources of Rent. But there are
bad abstractions as well as good,—abstractions which do not take in more
than a fraction of the facts, and that fraction perhaps the least
significant of all. They may be true in a sense, and yet be valueless. That
is to say, they may reproduce and represent with vividness some mere
circumstance connected with particular results, and yet miss completely the
essential conditions on which these results depend.
Ricardo's definition of Rent, as pruned and shaped
under the fire of criticism by later writers, is not only true, but it is a
truism. The Rent which any given piece of land will fetch is precisely the
excess of its value over another piece of Land which is too poor to fetch
any rent at all-' But we may well ask, like Eliphaz, the Temanite, when we
hear such a definition as this, "Should a wise man utter vain knowledge, and
fill his belly with the East wind?" This definition is true, not only of the
rent of land, but of the rent of all other things which fetch a price for
hire. The admirers of it sometimes boast. that the mere statement of it has
all the force of a self-evident proposition.' This, however, becomes very
doubtful praise when we observe that the same self-evident character follows
the definition when it is applied to the hire of a Costermonger's Donkey as
much as when ibis applied to the hire of a Farm. The value for hire of any
particular Donkey is obviously the value of its labour above that of any
other Donkey which will fetch no price at all for hire, but which works just
enough to pay for its own feeding. So in like manner the Rent of any given
House is the excess of its value for hire above that of some other House
which would fetch no rent at all, but which is used by Paupers as a Hovel.
In this form the proposition is true, but it is also barren. All the
corollaries which have been drawn from it in later speculations, are not
logical consequences at all, but are built up on verbal fallacies imported
into the definition by the careless use of ambiguous words. It certainly
does not prove, or tend to prove, that the Rent of agricultural land is no
element in the cost of Production,' because whatever may be the truth in
this matter, the Formula gives us no analysis of Rent, and tells us nothing
of its sources or of its composition. It is not very easy to see how the
hire of a Steam-Plough would be part of the cost of Production, whilst the
hire of a drain or of a fence would not. Yet the hire of such improvements
is a large element in Rent. Still less does the Formula prove that all the
growing values in all the Products of Labour, tend to become absorbed in the
Rent of land—a proposition in itself absurd, and opposed to all observation
and experience. The proportion of gross or total produce which goes to Rent
is not greater, but, on the contrary, it is smaller, as Agriculture becomes
more scientific. Nothing like one-third—the old Scotch proportion in rude
ages—of the gross produce, now goes to Rent. One-sixth or one-eighth is more
near the average proportion. More than before goes to Muscular Labour; more
goes to the breeder of Horses; more goes to the maker of machines; more goes
to the seller of manures, and, in average times, more to the Farmer. The
increase of Rent arises entirely from the enormous increase of total
produce, and from a corresponding increase of demand. This is the reason why
high rents are a sign of general prosperity.' If the sixth or the eighth of
the total produce be only ten shillings, then the total produce per acre
must be as low as £3 per acre or £4. This indicates wretched crops, or a
poor market, or both. If, on the other hand, the rent of land be sixty or
eighty shillings an acre, it proves that the total produce must be at least
£18 an acre or £24 —indicating abundant crops, and a good market. Both of
these are the signs of general activity and increasing wealth among all
classes. "A low rent," says a well-informed writer, "is always an index of
the poverty of the land, a thriftless and unscientific method of culture, or
a want of enterprise on the part of both Landlord and Tenant."' The
inference that all values are absorbed in Rent is absurd. But whether true
or false, such inferences as these have no foundation whatever in the
Ricardo Formula, in so far as that Formula expresses a self- evident
proposition. It has this self-evident character only when it is kept
strictly to a purely quantitative relation. It defines Rent only as regards
its amount or quantity, and in no other relation whatever. The moment it
pretends to explain Rent in any other of its many relations to the Past, or
to the Present, the Ricardo Formula passes beyond its province. It is a
definition dealing with quantity alone—and dealing with that element in Rent
in a form so elementary that its boasted self-evidence may freely be
conceded. It measures even quantity by a standard of comparison which is of
no practical use whatever. It assumes a Zero line—the existence of land
which will afford no Rent at all, or only a Rent which is nominal. It then
announces the profound con- elusion that all higher Rents are to be measured
in respect to quantity by their elevation above this Zero line. This is a
theoretical but a self-evident truth, even if we dispute as a fact (as well
we may) that there is any land except naked rock, which will yield no Rent
whatever.' But this self-evident truth is as naked as the only land which
answers to its description. It tells us nothing of any practical or even of
any speculative value.
By a curious coincidence I first heard this Ricardo
Formula for defining Rent, set forth, many years ago, by Lord Macaulay—the
only illustrious descendant and representative of the Clan on whose
reclaimed lands 1 had been born and bred. He had evidently very little
practical knowledge of the many economic elements which determine Rent, nor
probably had he ever thought of tracing the Historical elements which
explain its origin in the Past. On the other hand, at that time I had not
myself studied the subject theoretically; whilst, practically, I had a good
deal of instructive and significant experience. I recollect noticing the
evident intellectual pleasure with which he expounded a Doctrine which can
be so neatly expressed, and which assumes to set forth in so small a compass
one of the most complicated of all the facts of History and of Life. Not
less distinctly do I remember the sense of emptiness—the painful contrast,
as it struck me, between the self-evidence of the Definition, and the
sterility of it—not only as regarded any practical application, but even as
regarded any satisfying theoretical analysis.
This is but one example out of many of those methods
of handling which have brought Political Economy into its present disrepute,
as not only a "Dismal Science" but as a Body of Doctrine either actually
deceptive or at least to a very large extent misleading. No doubt part of
this eclipse in popular estimation, arises from nothing but ignorant
rebellion against some truths which are as certainly ascertained as any
other truths whatever. For this evil the only remedy, other than discussion,
will be found in those practical results of evil which must always follow,
sooner or later, from kicking against the pricks of Nature. This was the
teaching, for example, as we have seen, which led men at last, in Scotland,
to recognise the folly of Sumptuary Laws —of Laws forbidding men to sell or
buy except through certain Corporate Monopolies,—and of Laws which pretended
to regulate the price of anything. But Ignorances and Rebellions of this
kind, affecting our obedience to those Supreme Enactments which are enforced
by the high pains and penalties of Natural Consequence, are not the only
cause of the wide revolt which now assails the teaching that passes under
the name of Political Economy. Another cause is to be found in the fact that
this teaching has been often most defective, and, not seldom, even
thoroughly erroneous. One grand defect in it has been the comparative
neglect, and sometimes even the complete elimination, as not belonging to
its Province, of those agencies of Mind which are in reality the ultimate
sources of all that is done, or enjoyed or suffered, in Societies of Alen.
In undertaking to reduce the growth of Nations, and the progress of Mankind,
to causes as rigid and mechanical as those which govern the Material World,
it has missed the highest offices which it is its duty to discharge.
Political Economy, properly treated, ought not to be a Dismal Science. It
ought not to present results emptied of all adequate recognition of the work
done by Mind, and Heart, and Will. To pretend to explain the origin, or the
growth, or the distribution of Wealth—to explain anything, indeed, of the
past history or present condition of Man, without full recognition of these
great moving Forces, is like pretending to explain the cylinders, and the
tubes, and the valves of a Steam Engine without any reference to the
properties of Steam, and without any reference to the mechanical Invention
by which its pressures are generated, concentrated, and brought to bear on
Use. Against this kind of science, falsely so called, continual resistance
and revolt is both inevitable and just. On the other hand, when the Science
which deals with all these things, comes—if it ever does come—to be properly
handled, and when all the facts of our complicated nature are marshalled in
their due rank and order, it will be a Science full of all the interest, and
of all the poetry, and of all the pure intellectual delight, which must
belong to the contemplation and the analysis of Nature in the noblest of all
her Provinces.
Nothing, for example, can be more interesting or
instructive than to trace in the light of History the sources and the origin
of those relations between men which directly or indirectly exist in all
regions of the civilised world between Owners and Occupiers of the Soil. We
need not fill our bellies with East Wind in artificial definitions of Rent
which have nothing to do with either its origin or its nature. There is
really no difficulty in arriving at a definition which is not artificial,
but natural'—a, simple description of facts,—and one which nevertheless
immediately suggests questions leading up to higher and higher aspects of
the truth. Rent is that which one man pays for the temporary possession, or
exclusive use, of anything that is not his own, but is the permanent
property of another. Rent is the price of Hire. As regards this essential
and definite characteristic, it matters nothing what the thing thus hired
may be. In common parlance Rent is usually applied to the Hire of land, or
of Houses, or of Mines, or of Fishings, but is not usually applied to the
Hire of Horses, or of Carriages, or of other moveable property. Each of
these different things has its own peculiar kind of use, and each special
use holds out to us some special inducement to hire it. But no peculiarity
in the nature of the use constitutes any distinction in the principle of
Hire. That principle is the same in all cases in which we pay for the
temporary possession of anything that belongs to another. What we pay for,
when we hire anything, is the Exclusive Use or Possession of it, for a time.
And the price we pay for this Exclusive Use is paid to the man who himself
possesses it, and has the power of lending it. What we owe to him in the
form of Hire, or Rent, is due to him because of his exercising in our favour
his right and power of lending. If we want to have the Exclusive Use of a
Horse, or of a Cow, or of a Cabbage Garden, or of a Vineyard, or of a Farm,
we must hire this exclusive right for a time, if we cannot buy it out and
out.
If we go further and ask how the Owner came to have
that right of Exclusive Use which many other men can only afford to Hire, we
shall find that there is no difference in principle between the different
things over which this right has been acquired. It is true that the land of
the Cabbage Garden, or of the Vineyard, or of the Farm has not been the
creation of Muscular Labour. But neither have Cattle, nor Sheep, nor Horses
been the work of Muscle. The breeding of them is the work of Nature, under
the direction to some extent of a selecting Mind, and even this only
rendered possible by the right of Exclusive Use over at least some grazing
land. And so, although land is not in itself the produce either of Muscular
or of Mental Labour, yet the Exclusive Use of any part of it has always been
originally acquired by the work of Mind. To seek the origin of this
exclusive Right of Use we must go back to the Conquering Tribes from which
we are all descended. And then, again, to explain how they came to conquer,
we must always go back to some time, whether within the area of History or
beyond it, when the Men of Muscle surrounded some Man of Mind, lifted him
perhaps on their shields and shouted, "Be thou our acknowledged Strongest."'
In our own country this tracking of the ultimate sources of Ownership leads
us along no doubtful path—no mere faint indications interpreted by theory
and speculation. The footprints are revealed to us in no dim light of mere
tradition, but in the full blaze of History. We see men crowding under the
banner of powerful Chiefs, and seeking "rooms" of land under their
protection, because of the security it held out to them for Exclusive Use.
We see our early Kings, with the consent of Barons, Clergy, and People,
acknowledging the power of those Chiefs as a Power which had been
established long before, and tendering to those who held it a new Form of
Record as a reward for new, but immortal, services. Poetry and Sentiment
could hardly have a better subject. The Recording Instruments may have been
long lost—they may be now reduced to pulp in damp cellars, or in neglected
Charter-Chests —or they may have been happily preserved with their old
Parchments, and their old stately Seals. But whether surviving in this form
or not, they live in the continuous transactions of perhaps a thousand
years. That which men have been holding—that which they have been buying and
selling during all these centuries—has been the Tenure which these
Instruments record. Over the whole of Scotland every morsel of land which is
owned or hired for the exclusive use of any man, is held by him in virtue of
the Rights of Predecessors in Title dating from before the times of Malcolm
Canmore, or from the years of contest that were closed at Bannockburn.
The aptitudes of Mind are infinite—or at least as
various as all the varieties of circumstance in which the Human Species has
been placed since it was born into the world. Nothing can be done without it
and everything that has been done, has been done by it. In early ages,
courage and conduct in War has been the form of mental energy most
effective. But this is generally a compound of many qualities. The influence
of some men cannot be explained. It is magnetic. In their presence other men
become excited with a fire which is not their own. Without such Minds, mere
numbers are of no avail —for the units become as incoherent as grains of
sand. Such men become the Founders of Nations because of the confidence they
inspire—of the ideas they represent—and of the Institutions which they
inaugurate. One of the very first works which they accomplish is, the
establishment of supreme and exclusive dominion over some portion of the
Earth's surface for themselves and for their immediate followers. This right
of Exclusive Use is subdivided and partitioned in a thousand ways. But in
its essence and in its principle it is everywhere the same. It is, in its
very inception, the fruit of Mind, and it affords the only fulcrum on which
Mind can exert its higher powers over the Increase of the Earth during the
more peaceful ages which follow, and are the rewards of, Conquest.
Examples have not been wanting in our own day, which
exhibit the power of one gifted Mind so to discipline the forces of mere
Muscle, and the labour of comparatively mindless men, as to lay the
foundations of a civilised State. General Gordon was unquestionably one of
those men—whose heroic nature represents, as Muscle never can represent,
those supreme forms of "Labour" on which all Wealth, and Comfort, and Law
depend. And it is remarkable that when he was first ruling as Governor of
Khartoum, one of the most immediate and striking effects of his dominion,
was a revival of that cultivation of the soil which is inseparable from
individual appropriation, or Exclusive Use. Tracts of land which had been
desolate for generations, became cultivated again, simply because the Owners
were secured under his dominion against the inroads of men who would not
respect the rights of Exclusive Use. If General Gordon had been a Native
Ruler, or a Native Chief, having extensive Territorial rights over the
Soudan, and depending for the maintenance of his power upon native revenues,
the private Owners to whom the fruits and rights of Ownership had been thus
restored, would have been only too glad to yield to him no inconsiderable
share of these fruits, which could not be enjoyed except under the
protection he afforded.
There may be other cases in which the individual
appropriation of ]and, and the acknowledged right to its Exclusive Use, has
arisen from other causes. Indeed, it may be said with truth to be a
universal and apparently a necessary fact in every portion of the Globe, and
with every branch of the human family. One of the most prominent Socialistic
theorists' who now denounce it, is himself one of a small group of men—less
than one- quarter of the population of London—who claim Exclusive Use over
the whole State of California, embracing about ninety-nine millions of
acres, or 156,000 square miles of plain and valley, of mountain and of hill.
No part of this vast territory is open to all mankind—except upon the
conditions imposed by this small community. But like all other communities
in like circumstances—like all the colonies of our own Empire—they not only
practise the individual appropriation of land among their own citizens, but
they recognise it as the foundation of their prosperity. What they all want
is Settlers; and what all Settlers want is land on which they can exercise
their industry for their own benefit and the benefit of the world. Some
evidence of truth is always afforded by the universal instincts of Mankind.
The celebrated test which has been put to very doubtful use in Theology, has
nevertheless its own sphere of legitimate application - "Quod semper - quod
ubique - quod ab omnibus."' The most experienced travellers in Africa tell
us that there is no portion of that vast Continent which is not claimed in
Ownership by some Tribe, and the invasion of which by others would not be
resented and resisted by those who thus claim its Exclusive Use. If there be
any portions of the Earth's surface where individual appropriation might be
less absolutely necessary than another, as regards the means of subsistence,
it would seem to be in those happy Islands of the Eastern Archipelago where
wild and native trees bear the most nutritious fruits, and the vegetable
world holds out the most lavish inducements to an idle communal existence.
Yet I find in an interesting account of New Guinea by a Highlander who has
devoted himself to Missionary Work in the Pacific, the following instructive
passage respecting that immense Island:-" Far up the distant mountain sides,
in the clear atmosphere of morning, we saw the smoke made in the Bush by
cultivators of yams. The Teachers assert that every acre of soil along this
part of New Guinea has its Owner."'
There is no Political Eonomist, to whatever School he
may belong, however narrow may be his formule, and however narrower still
may be his use and his interpretation of them, who does not at least confess
with his lips that "Labour" must be held to include every kind and form of
Human Energy. Yet very few writers have really digested this truth,—have
taken adequate account of it in their reasonings,—or have attempted to
follow it to all its consequences. The great difference between the wages of
Skilled and of Unskilled Labour is one of the most rudimentary facts of Life
which indicate the value of the mental element even in its simplest forms.
The simplest of these forms is that in which some special faculty of
Perception is united in the same person with the Labour of the Hands. But
all the higher forms of Mental Energy are, for the most part, not united in
the same person with the Labour of the Hands. It is the value and effect of
these higher Energies of Mind which are most habitually forgotten, and in
almost all Treatises on questions of human Progress the word Labour
gradually slips down—and down—in its use and signification, until
practically it means nothing but the Labour of the Hands, with the more or
less implicit addition, only of the various degrees of mere technical or
manipulative skill. "The producing Classes"-"The produce of Labour," and
many other similar phrases, are perpetually used as if Muscle only were
concerned in the sources, or in the increase, or in the diffusion, of
Wealth. Nothing can be more erroneous, and yet the error has never been
sufficiently exposed. The Modern Socialist School are especially forgetful
of Mind in all its highest and most operative powers, and are especially
jealous of those facts—the most certain perhaps of all facts—which establish
the natural, ineradicable, and far-reaching inequalities with which these
powers have been bestowed by Nature on individual men. All the writers of
this School dislike and avoid the subject, and, when they do deal with it,
show how very little they recognise or appreciate the real facts of Nature.
The most signal example I have seen of the measureless
difference between these facts and the Socialist appreciation of them, is
the example to be found in some words of Mr. Henry George: "I doubt if any
good observer will say that the mental differences of men are greater than
the physical differences."' Here we have a comparison made between two
things which are absolutely incommensurable. It may be quite true that the
tallest Giant ever known is scarcely more than four times as tall as the
smallest Dwarf. It may be true that the average difference in height between
men. does not exceed one-sixth, or one-seventh of the whole stature. It may
be true that the scale of difference in muscular strength—in the lifting of
weights, for example— is a scale not much wider in its extremes. But most
certainly it is not true that even in those lower manifestations of Mind
which constitute mere manual dexterity and skill in handicrafts, the
differences between men, are like mere bodily differences, either in kind or
in degree. A short man may be as good for all manly work as a tall man—or an
ugly man as a man of the most perfect form. But in Mechanics, or in
Chemistry, or in Art, the corresponding differences of skill make the whole
contrast between work which is useless or effective—healing or
poisonous—hideous or of surpassing beauty. To Be, or Not To Be this, and no
less, is the question which may depend, and often does depend, upon the
degrees of Faculty with which the eyes are directed, or the hands are moved.
Still more futile is this comparison of physical distinctions as any
illustration of the differences which separate one man from another in the
higher faculties of the Mind. The difference between a dull man and a man of
genius—whatever the particular line of that genius may be—is a difference so
immense as to be immeasurable. The scale is one which reaches from Zero to a
practical Infinity. Moreover, it is a scale of difference applicable above
all to those kinds of Work on which Society is founded, and by which its
progress is determined. There is no scale that can measure the difference,
in actual working value, between the Mind of James Watt and the Mind of the
most skilled Workmen whom he employed to make, first, his Models, and then,
his Engines. But great as this difference is, it is perhaps exceeded by the
difference between the average faculties of ordinary men, and those rarer
gifts which in the early stages of Society are concerned in founding its
Organic Structures, and in establishing its Opportunities of Growth. Yet as
regards physical powers, there is often little or nothing to distinguish
between such men; and certainly no physical difference could even be a
symbol, however imperfect, of the differences of level on which they stand.
It is one of the regrets of my life that I once had a
long interview with General Gordon when I did not even know who he was. It
was before the time of his greatest fame, but when in a very distant region
he had done enough to indicate what manner of man he was. There was,
however, nothing in his outward appearance to arrest attention. There was no
aspect of command. There was no look of genius in his almost cold, grey eye.
There was no indication in his calm manner, of the Fires of God that were
slumbering underneath—of the powerful yet gentle nature which was equally at
home in the "confused noise" of Battle, in the teaching of poor children, or
in the comforting of a deathbed. Yet General Gordon was one who even then
had saved an Empire, and had rescued, by his own individual example and
force of character, a whole population from massacre and devastation. Not,
perhaps, very tractable in council—sometimes almost incoherent in
speculative opinion—he was, beyond all question, a born Ruler and King of
men —one who in early ages might have been the founder of a Nation—the
Chosen Leader of some Chosen People on the way from intertribal wars and
barbarism to peace, and Government, and Law. To say of such men as Gordon
that the difference between them and the common herd, is no greater than the
difference between men of the biggest and the smallest size of body that may
be picked off the street, is to betray a profound ignorance of the causes
and the forces which have governed the history of Mankind. Nor does it need
such an ex- treme case to illustrate the fallacy. The varieties of Mind are
infinite, and the pre-eminence of one over another in some special
faculty—some single gift—may, and often does, make the whole difference
between victory and defeat-between triumphant success and total failure, in
the race of individual life, and in the struggle between Tribes and Nations.
The protection of the Powerful has been in all ages
the earliest shelter for the beginnings of industry and of wealth. In our
own country we have traced these beginnings from before the dawn of
History—when Power was establishing itself through all the various gifts and
aptitudes which made some men Kings, and Chiefs, and Leaders, by clustering
round them all who could not otherwise defend themselves. The Exclusive Use
of land, whether by small groups or by individual men, has always been
absolutely necessary for the production and enjoyment of even the simplest
of its fruits; and this Exclusive Use could not be had without coming under
the protection of those who had become Owners, who could defend their
Ownership, and who could defend also those to whom they let it, or lent it,
for a time. Rent, originally and historically, was the price men were too
glad to pay for this protection. This element in Rent is still expressed in
every Lease by words which in one form or another have been continuously
used for 700 years, and which embodied in language understandings which were
necessary and universal. They are words which convey the promise that
Tenants will be protected in their Exclusive Use "at all hands, and against
all mortals." Sometimes the words were shorter—" against all deadly." This
was the Occupier's Tenure. This was his Security. This was the one
fundamental advantage for which men owed, and gladly paid, some portion of
Produce, or of their own Muscular Labour, or of both.
But from very early times another element was added to
the benefits for which Produce and Services were paid. Owners lent not only
the Exclusive Use of land, but also the cattle by which the land was
stocked. We have seen that this form of what on the Continent is called "Metayer,"
was common over the whole of Scotland under the name of "Steelbow."' Next
came a further change—another addition, or rather another great group of
additions, to the benefits for which Rent was paid. These additions
included, in the first place, all those exercises of Mind and of Authority
by which ignorant and wasteful Usages were abolished, and all those by which
the new methods of husbandry were taught and first estab- lished. They
included, in the second place, all that we now know under the head of
Reclamation and Permanent Improvements,—operations which have in all cases
far exceeded the capital value of the Land before they began. The Burst of
Industry which I have described as having begun to transform the face of
Scotland during the latter half of the last century, did not end with a
Burst, but has been continuous and increasing ever since. On this point I
can speak from personal experience. Some parts of the "Old Coast Line" on
which I have described the operations of Lord Frederick Campbell, were still
left unreclaimed when I began the work of Ownership forty years ago. I found
that the cost of bringing them into the condition of arable land was not
less than, and sometimes exceeded, £25 an acre. As in its unreclaimed state
the land was not worth 5s. an acre of the coarsest pasture, this outlay
represents one hundred years' purchase of its original value. Sentiment,—of
one kind,—has often led me to desire to see, even if it were only for a
moment, the aspect of our country when, before the days even of the Picts
and Scots, it was covered by magnificent and continuous Forests—where not a
stick has grown within the memory of Man, or within the records of authentic
History. But as this revival cannot be, Sentiment—of another kind—has led me
lately to dig up the trunks of the Caledonian Forest, and to cover with
corn-fields some areas which have been for many centuries under bog. One of
these seems to have been a glade shaded by giant Oaks. Here again my
experience has been that the outlay is far beyond—sometimes forty and fifty
times beyond—the capital value of the land as it stood when I began. But
reclamations effected thus suddenly, and by one single operation, are few in
comparison with those other reclamations which have been gradual and
continuous during many generations - each successive work bringing up the
condition of the land to the standard of knowledge existing at the time. I
have found that in the West of Scotland, where there is a very heavy
rainfall, and where great areas of country are far from Tileworks, the mere
re-drainage of old cultivated land cannot be thoroughly done, at the present
or recent prices of Muscular Labour and of Material, at a less cost than
from £10 to £12 per acre; and this alone is very frequently more than twenty
years' purchase of the former rent.
But there is another kind of outlay connected with
modern husbandry which has been on an enormous scale, the work of Ownership
in Scotland, especially during the last forty years. Up to about that time,
over the greater part of the country, it had been one of the customary
stipulations in Leases that the Tenants should erect new Houses, with such
assistance as in each case might be agreed upon. This stipulation was
connected with the abandonment of Township Hovels, and of Runrig Tillage.
The new class of Houses, although an immense advance on the old huts of
Wattles and turf, were generally built of stone without lime and with roofs
of thatch. Comfortable and commodious as these Houses often were when
compared with the squalid dwellings which had preceded them, they still left
much to be desired when compared with the advancing tastes and knowledge of
the day. Accordingly, in almost all cases, Tenants taking farms during later
years, have offered their new rents upon condition of getting the farms
furnished with new Houses, both for themselves and for their Cows and other
stock. On this branch of the Work of Ownership, I can also speak from a
somewhat large and long experience. It is quite impossible to graduate the
outlay on Houses according to the scale of Rent. Certain requirements apply
equally to a Farm of £100 a year, and to a farm of £500 a year. I have
rarely succeeded in building a "Steading" or complete set of Farm Buildings,
under at least five years' outlay of the improved rent. Nine and ten years'
outlay is common; and in the case of small Farms of between £100 and £200,
the outlay has been as high as sixteen years of the rent. The general result
is that the capital represented by Ownership in Scotland is seldom less than
from forty to fifty years' rental, and is very often a great deal more. The
average capital of Tenants is certainly less than five years of the rental
per acre. I have elsewhere' specified the case of one farm in which the
capital of the Owner represents the sum of £7046, whilst that invested by
the Tenant would represent, on a liberal computation, not more than £966.
The results of any improvement which such a Tenant can make upon his farm
must be always in greatest measure due to sources which he did not
contribute. He is trading on the capital, on the previous improvements, and
on the ancient Ownership, of other men. Yet there are politicians and
economists who recommend that a Tenant who builds a new piggery or a new
silo, at the cost of some fraction of a year's rent, should be allowed to
deprive Owners of the rights which flow from centuries of Tenure and of
outlay, by selling the occupancy which has been lent to them for a time upon
stipulated conditions.
These facts, and a host of others correlative to
these, open up an immense subject. If writers on Political Economy and on
Social problems of any kind, would not only say, but would practically
remember that Labour means every form and kind and degree of Human Energy,
and most especially all those kinds which were the earliest and are the
highest, their "Science" would not be the dismal, lean and erroneous
teaching which too often it has been found out to be. Abstractions from
which everything has been subtracted that ought to have been
included—arbitrary selections and as arbitrary rejections among the elements
contributing to great results—slovenly analysis, and complete forgetfulness
of essential things which are by way of being left to be understood,—all
these sources of error leave but a poor and beggarly account of the
inexhaustible riches and Poetry of Nature, in the true history and progress
of Man. The multitude of mental agencies, and of powers—the complexit of the
sources, and of the opportunities of war —dating back through many
centuries, with which, and upon which, every man trades in Scotland who
hires any land belonging to another—but none of which are due to the
hirer—are but the type of a general truth, affecting more or less all
callings or employments. When Men are taught that they ought to have the
"whole value of their own Labour," they are never taught to count and
estimate all the factors which go to make up the total value of results to
which, perhaps, their own contribution may be the smallest. They do not
think of the Capital which is the savings of Mind, of the Organisation which
is the invention of Mind—of the Enterprise and Confidence which are the
expectations of Mind—of the Law which is the embodiment of Mind,—on all of
which the whole of their own opportunities have absolutely depended. And yet
these considerations are not founded on theory or speculation. They are
founded on indisputable facts, and are brought to light as facts by the very
simple process of analysing with care and accuracy the conditions of our own
life, and the meaning of the commonest words in which we instinctively
express them.
The great interest and value of the history of
Scotland regarding all these matters, lie in its splendid continuity. Like
the days of the Poet, our generations have been "bound each to each by
natural piety."' From the days when her early Sovereigns, in the Eleventh
and Twelfth Centuries, gathered round them the Barons and Knights and the
Burgesses of the Kingdom, and gave them new Instruments recording and
defining the rights and powers which they had even then immemorially
enjoyed—from the time when Robert the Bruce emerged triumphant from the War
of Independence, and transferred these rights and powers from men who had
been faithless, to men who had been faithful to their Country—from the time
when he rewarded by a fresh and noble Tenure those who had stood by his side
from Methven Bridge to Bannockburn,—the history of Scotland has been one
long and steady development of the Reign of Mind in Government and in Law.
The amalgamation of Races—the blending of interests—the fusion of
Classes—the freedom of trade—the local movements of population in the rise
of new industries,—these have been the lines of its long rough but steady
march from extreme poverty and rudeness, to great wealth, and great
achievements in every walk of intellectual exertion.
There are drawbacks and limitations to progress in all
Nations, and it would be alike foolish and dangerous to forget them. But it
is certainly not true that the immense increase of Wealth in Scotland since
the Union has been an increase not widely distributed over the bulk of her
population. The wages of her artificers, by no means the highest in skill,
who are now employed on the Industries of the Clyde, amount very often in a
single month to more money, with ten times the purchasing power, than the
whole yearly income enjoyed by their fathers a hundred years ago. The same
contrast is presented in every walk of life. The Houses and Cottages which
all Owners have been building for Tenants during the last fifty years, are
palaces compared—not only with the huts of the corresponding classes in the
Military Ages, but compared even with the Houses lived in by powerful Chiefs
not longer than a century and a half ago. The multiplication of Villas and
Houses of a high class along all our shores, and round the old centres of
our great cities, represents an immense aggregate of comfortable means among
all the classes engaged in Trade and Commerce. The condition of our great
cities is justly attracting attention, and much remains to be done for them
in lines of action which cannot be too earnestly considered. But the more
carefully we look into the Past, the more we shall be thankful for the
general direction of the path in which, as a Nation, we have been led.
No man was more deeply versed in the literature of the
Past—in the details of life during the Military Ages—than the late Mr.
Cosino Innes. He did not escape altogether from that curious form of
Sentiment which tempts us all at times to long for a Wild Life, and to wish
that our wild land had remained for ever unreclaimed—that our mountains had
remained for ever waste. Under the influence of this strange glamour, which,
as we have seen, never has any power as regards the Lowlands, he has allowed
himself in one passage to take strange liberties with History and with
Logic. He suggests that all the wild surfaces of our Country were not really
intended to be conveyed by Charter, because in those days they were not
really thought of Yet in another passage of the same Essay, when dealing
with the express words of these Charters, which carefully and exhaustively
enumerated every variety of surface within the boundaries of an Estate, he
explains that these enumerations were introduced ob majorem cautelam—or, in
other words, from the very excess of thoughtfulness. Of course this—the only
irrational passage in all the writings of a very learned man—is the only one
ever quoted by the irrational and the sentimental. Yet I know few writings
more rich in evidence of all the leading facts and inferences which have
been set forth in the preceding chapters----those especially which show us
at once the connection and the contrast between the past and the present
condition of our country. The original identity of Celtic Institutions with
those of the other Northern Nations—differing only in the longer survival of
early customs, and in the want of any code to define or fix;' the gradual
adoption of Saxon Laws, not as alien or as the result of conquest, but
because there was nothing definite to be displaced, and because those laws
were in their nature "the most approved—the most civil;" the extent of
exactions imposed upon the people during the Military Ages; the fractionally
small portion of the country which was cultivated at all, this portion being
confined to a narrow strip on the river bank, or beside the sea; the
miserable use to which even those small areas were put that were grazed at
all—just serving to keep the cattle from starvation; the constant quarrels
arising out of the common use of pastures; the great excess of population
which arose in the Glens over the number which the country could support
with its own produce "or honestly;" the enormous waste involved in the
neglect and utter vacancy of vast areas of mountain land—stretching, on one
Estate, across the whole of Scotland from sea to sea, and yielding literally
nothing to represent "the thousands and millions of sheep which graze them
now;" the beginnings of improvement in the obligatory stipulations imposed
on Tenants by Owners in the terms of Leases, so early as 1511 the
enforcement of all such stipulations by the penalty of removal or dismissal
from the Estate; the safety of the evidence that the small cultivators and
subtenants, now called Crofters, were then Tenants at Will; —all these, and
many other kindred facts, testify, first, to the rude and barbarous
condition of our ancestors, and, next, to the powers and processes by which
their children have been raised to an acknowledged place among the most
civilised nations in the world. The contrast is indeed astonishing. "Always
on the verge of famine and every few years suffering the horrors of actual
starvation"—such are the words in which this careful Historian describes the
old condition of the Highlands. There is no wonder that he is roused to
something like enthusiasm when in the case of a particular Estate,—that of
the Campbells of Cawdor in Nairn,—he sees and describes all the poetry of a
most blessed change:-" The woods now wave over the grey Castle with a
luxuriance of shade which its old inhabitants never thought of. Above all,
the country round, of old occupied by a half-starving people, lodged in
houses of 'faile,' 1 disturbed by plundering neighbours, and ever and anon
by the curse of Civil War, is now cultivated by an active and thriving
Tenantry, with the comforts which increasing intelligence and wealth require
and supply."' This is a beautiful vignette. But, again, this is only a
little bit out of a 'wide landscape, which carries into the mind, through
the eye, certain .convictions in which we cannot be deceived.
And so it happens again that Mr. Cosmo Innes when, in
another Work, he finds himself in contact with the actual records of old
times, and with the picture they present of life and manners, was, as we all
must be, recalled to the realities of historic truth. In closing his Preface
to that instructive record of life on a great Highland Estate during three
Centuries, which is contained in the Book of Taymouth, he expresses his
general conclusion in these remarkable words:-" While there is enough of
romance in the glimpses here opened of the rough life of the 'good old
time,' it is pleasant to think that while much is changed, every change has
been for the better. The country which these papers show us in so wild a
state of lawless insecurity has for the last two centuries steadily
improved, and the process has not been more marked in the face of the
country than in the moral and physical condition of the people and their
social happiness." Yet this is spoken of a district in the Highlands from
which there was as large a movement of population, in connection with the
Industrial Age, as from any other portion of the country.
Among the many delusions which a false sentiment has
promoted there has, perhaps, never been a delusion more complete than that
which imagines that in early Celtic Customs or traditions, as distinguished
from the corresponding Customs and traditions of the Teutonic Nations, there
was any element which, if it had been left alone, would have built up some
Polity better for the mass of the people than the Polity which actually
arose, out of the amalgamation of the races, in England and in Scotland. As
it so happens, we have historical evidence on this subject, more ancient,
more continuous, and more conclusive, than on any other subject whatever
connected with the rise of civilisation in any part of Europe. In an earlier
chapter I have already referred to the curiously narrow and local, but
attractive culture of the early Celtic Church. It is beyond question that
the Monks and Priests of that Church had some culture and some letters in a
literature purely Celtic, at a time when the other modern European nations
were either sunk in utter barbarism, or at least were so little advanced as
to have nothing of the same kind. But from this very fact we have an amount
of evidence in respect to the condition and habits of these Celts, which we
do not possess in respect to any other European race whatever at the same
date. In the Annals of Ireland by the Four Masters we have a continuous
Chronicle which is supposed, on good grounds, to be substantially authentic
from the Second Century of the Christian Era. Even if this very early date
be doubted, there seems to be no doubt whatever that these Annals are
authentic from at least the Fourth Century, and they are continuous down to
the middle of the Seventeenth. They present to us all the chief incidents of
each year which were considered worthy of record by men of the most educated
and intelligent class in Ireland. The result is to show that not only were
the whole conditions of Society barbarous in the sense of being rude, rough,
and violent but that they were barbarous in the sense of being exceptionally
savage, and without a trace of amelioration or of progress towards better
things.
There may be a high interest attaching to Warlike
Tribes—if their Wars have in them even the germ of contests animated by
nobler passions than the mere thirst for blood, or the mere triumphs of
revenge. But we may turn over page after page of these Annals without seeing
even one solitary symptom of the crystallising forces which begin the
Organic Structures of Civilisation. Every page is a sickening repetition of
intertribal battles, murders, and devastations. Taking only the period
before the English Conquest by Henry Plantagenet, we have the record of
about 700 years. Not one single step can be traced through all those
centuries in the path of progress. On the contrary, the country was getting
worse and worse. And yet there as Poetry and Sentiment—of a kind. One of the
most curious features of the Monkish Journals is the constant bursting of
the narrative into verse— couplets and quatrains of rhythmic utterance. Few
of us can judge of any beauty which may belong to them in the Erse. But we
can all judge of the meanings and passions which inspired them. There are
some allusions to Nature—to the Sea—to Rivers—to Mountains—which are poetic.
But the animating spirit is almost purely ferocious—with nothing of the
higher sentiments which we understand as Patriotism. No deeds of massacre,
however dreadful, are ever narrated with rebuke—still less any acts of mere
plunder—unless, perchance, any of these should have been directed against
Ecclesiastics. Then indeed the culprit "King" or Chief is denounced as a
monster, and some rival King or Chief is incited—in piteous or in furious
appeals—to punish him with death and with the devastation of his country.
Thus in the year 733 we are told in the Annals that a Celtic King had
ventured to practise upon some Church or Convent one of those exactions, "Coigny,"
which were universally practised against all the laity. He had forcibly
taken some "refection" from a Church called "Cill-Cunna." For this offence
another King was incited by "Congus, successor of Patrick," to take bloody
vengeance on his too hungry rival. As usual there was a great battle. On the
way to it the avenging King bursts into this characteristic poetical
effusion:-
"For Cill-Cunna, the Church of my Confessor, I take
this journey on the road; Aedh IRoin shall leave his head with me, or
I shall leave mine with him."
And then we have the result chronicled thus:-
"The slaughter of the Ulidians with Aedh Roin by
Aedh Allan, King of Ireland, For their Coigny at Cill-Cunna he placed
soles to necks."
This last image may be very beautiful and poetic in
Erse, but in Anglo-Saxon it requires explanation. Accordingly the meaning is
given in a note by the learned Editor, as follows:-"This is an idiom
expressing indiscriminate carnage, in which the sole of the foot of one body
was placed over against or across the neck or headless trunk of another."
It would be easy to fill whole chapters with extracts
of the same kind. Many of them would exhibit the misery of the people. One
of them celebrates a battle of which it is specially recorded "Great the
carnage of Fir Feini," which is explained to be the "Farmers"' or
Cultivating Class. Down to the very latest date in these Annals the same
spirit is exhibited. The glory of a great Irish Chief who died in Rome so
late as 1616, is celebrated in the last pages of the last volume. He is
praised as "a warlike, valorous, predatory, enterprising Lord." The truth
is, that the Celtic race, like many others, were first lifted above
themselves by contact and mixture with other blood. By themselves they had
not only failed to advance, but they had fallen back. They had declined from
the doctrines and the practice even of their own Brehon Laws. The Colony
which they sent out to Scotland in the Sixth Century, rose, and has risen,
in exact proportion as it became thoroughly mixed and fused with the
Teutonic people. England gained immensely by both the Conquests which were
effected over her. Scotland gained quite as much by the more peaceful but
equally effective processes through which Saxon and Norman blood established
itself even in the remotest Highlands. Ireland has suffered not from the
Conquest, but because the higher Rule and Law were so long limited to the
Pale. No corner of Europe needed so much that work of complete amalgamation
which has given all its strength and power to the British people.
There is, however, one fruitful branch of the national
life of Scotland to which I cannot now direct any adequate attention, but to
which I must shortly refer in closing. This fruitful branch is that which
consists in the life and labours of men of the Celtic race, who have moved
out from their native hills and glens, and have given the benefit of high
culture, or of a rich and imaginative character, to their country and to the
world. Two examples of this kind are impressed upon my memory by
circumstances which have left an indelible impression. Many years ago I was
speaking to Lord Macaulay on the subject of the Indian Code of Criminal Law,
to which, in his own earlier life, he had devoted his learning and his
genius. He had occasion to mention the difficulties of the work—the deep
questions of Jurisprudence which it involved, and the sources from which he
had sought and found assistance. Amongst these he mentioned especially the
name of a man of whom at that time I had never heard—one of those who work
unseen in our Civil Services, and to whom the Nation very often is indebted
for far more than it ever comes to know. This was Sir John M'Leod, a native
of Skye, and one of the smaller Proprietors in that Island. Lord Macaulay
was not a man to lavish praise indiscriminately. His mind was critical, and
lie had of necessity in his own nature a very high standard in judging of
intellectual powers. It was therefore with some surprise that I heard Lord
Macaulay speak in almost enthusiastic praise of this little- known
descendant of the old MacLeods of Skye, as having one of the most profound,
sagacious, and philosophic minds he had ever met with.' When I came to know
Sir John M'Leod as I afterwards did, I found in him the perfect type of a
highly cultured son of the Celtic race—modest, refined, dignified,—and
speaking English, after some forty years' service abroad, with as strong a
Gaelic tone and accent as if he had never left his Estate in Skye.
But I recall another example somewhat different in
kind. A curious habit of the Highland people serves to conceal sometimes the
part they have played in the highest walks of human enterprise. This is the
habit of changing their name—dropping one and assuming another. During the
Military Ages they did so perpetually, as we have seen, when they enlisted
under some new Chief, and joined some other Clan. In assuming the name of
their new associates they kept up that theory and flavour of
blood-relationship which in nine cases out of ten had no other foundation
whatever. Sir Walter Scott tells us that one of his friends, shooting in the
North, had a native guide assigned to him under the name of Gordon. But he
recognised the man as having served him in a similar capacity some years
before in another place under the name of MacPherson. On asking the man
whether he was not the same, and whether his name had not then been
MacPherson, the composed reply was, "Yes, but that was when I lived on the
other side of the hill." It is less known, however, that this habit has
always been very general when Highlanders leave the hills and settle in the
Low Country. The native Celtic name is dropped, and some Lowland form is
adopted which is supposed to be a translation or an equivalent. It was thus
that during the scarcities and distress which afflicted the Hebrides during
the last years of the last century - about 1792 - a family of the name of
MacLeay migrated from the Islet of Ulva, one of the broken fragments of the
volcanic Island of Mull, and settled at Blantyre, near Glasgow. The name
they took was Livingstone, and their illustrious grandchild was the great
African Traveller and Missionary. The purity of the true old Celtic race
cannot be safely determined by name or language. Long centuries of foreign
dominion, and of intercourse and inter-marriage, leave it very doubtful
where we can find, even in the Hebrides, anything like an unmixed descent.
But having had the honour of a somewhat intimate friendship with David
Livingstone, I always regarded him as an example of the purest Celtic type.
Rather below the medium stature, broad, sturdy, and with an evident capacity
for great endurance, the special feature which attracted notice was his very
dark hazel eye—an eye so dark as almost to suggest a Southern or an Eastern
origin. Great self-possession and dignity of manner were blended with a
curious mixture of gentleness and determination. Nothing in Nature escaped
his observation; and shortly before his death I had a letter from him,
written in Central Africa, alluding to a peculiarity of growth in a tree at
Inveraray which I had not before noticed, but which he must have noticed in
silence when we were together. He was another instance of a man like General
Gordon, with a special gift and a special inspiration, which in all human
probability would never have been developed if he had been born in the life
passed by the old Sub-tenants in TJlva. Burning a little Kelp, digging a few
Potatoes, or even herding Cattle in the summer Shealings which looked down
on
"all the group of Islets gay That guard famed
Staffa round,"
is a life which it is difficult to rank at its proper
level as compared with that which he actually led —a life in which he became
to millions of the human race the first Pioneer of Civilisation, and the
first Harbinger of the Gospel.
The blood and the race which in our own day have
produced two such men - one from the class of Chiefs, and another from the
class of ordinary Clansmen,—must have the very best stuff of human nature in
it. But that blood and race is not confined to those who still retain the
Gaelic speech. The larger and the more cultivated part of it is spread over
the wide Dominions of the British Crown. It is one of the many, sources of
our Imperial strength and wealth. The Low Country of Scotland is full of it.
The Colonies are full of it. The Indian Services have always been full of
it. The Army and the Navy have had abundant reason to be proud of it. It was
trusted by The Bruce in the thickest of the Fights he fought. But its whole
pride, and aim, and object must continue to be those which that great King
promoted—the object of living and working in harmony with the other elements
which have built up the Scottish Nation, and in obedience to those Natural
and Moral Laws which are the only solid foundation of all Human
Institutions.
The progress that Scotland made after union with
England, was a progress without a parallel in any of the older Nations of
the World. Yet that progress was not due to anything she derived from
England in the way of Laws and Institutions. These were all her own. She
kept them at the Union, and guarded them, with a noble, because a grateful,
care. We were jealous about them, not from any narrow or provincial
feeling,—but because our fathers had told us of the noble works done in
their days, and in the old times before them. The one great benefit which
Scotland did owe to the last and happiest of her many unions, was nothing
more than access to larger fields of exercise to wider openings of
Opportunity. She rose to the immense prospects of this new horizon because
of the Mind and Character which had been developed under the long
discipline, and through the fiery trials, of her own stormy history. The
wonderful start she made in the race of intellectual and industrial Life,
was due to that history—to the older unions effected during it—to the
doctrines it had embodied--to the energies it had developed—to the great
principles of Jurisprudence which had worked under the sanctions, and with
the authority, of Law. Scotland, therefore, at the Union, did not break with
her own Past. On the contrary, she kept it, and cherished it, as the richest
contribution she could make to the growth of One Great Empire, and to the
Polity of One United Kingdom. Let her keep it still—and always in the same
spirit, and with the same great end in view.
|