WE now come to that other great branch of historical
inquiry which concerns not the Ownership but the cultivating Occupation of
the land. At first sight, and looking only to the surface of things, it
might seem as if the effect of Charters, however favourable to those who got
them, might be unfavourable to those who had only subordinate interests in
the soil. And so it would, if Charters had been what we have seen that they
were not. If the powers and attributes which they recognised as belonging to
Leadership over men, and to Ownership of land, had been new inventions,
introduced for the first time by a foreign and a conquering race, they might
have, and probably they would have, worked injuriously. But as those powers
and attributes were nothing of the kind,—as they were, on the contrary,
purely indigenous and of strictly native growth, they worked, and were
worked in the spirit of the new Form, and of the new embodiment which had
come to them with the increase of legal knowledge, and the progress of
civilisation. In this distinction lies the whole difference between life and
death in all human Institutions. For in them the same law prevails which in
organic bodies is called the "correlation of growth "—that law in virtue of
which all healthy developments in one member are surely, though often
invisibly, accompanied by corresponding and closely related developments in
many surrounding parts. in secrecy and in silence, through all the centres
of influence and all the germs of growth, the Formative Energy which governs
and directs the whole, builds up along a thousand lines the parallel
structures which are needed for the harmony of Life.
Nor, in the case
before us, is there any mystery as to the nature of the processes which ran
below and above, and alongside of each other, in the Age of Charters. It is
true that these Instruments imposed no limits on the fulness of that
Possession which they were intended to convey. On the contrary, it was the
special object of them to make that Possession as full and secure as
possible. But it is equally true that the fundamental conception of all
Charters was that of legal definition, and the substitution of fixed and
definite obligations for liabilities which were incalculable because they
were purely arbitrary, casual, and lawless. This fundamental conception, in
giving birth to Charters, gave birth at the same time, and of necessity, to
other Instruments of a like nature, which were derivative and subordinate.
It inspired the whole series of transactions which were in any way related
to the same subject. Men who accepted from the Crown, or from great Subjects
of the Crown, Charters of land on the emphatic condition that these lands
were to be free from the ungoverned and ungovernable usages of Celtic
Feudalism—"the exactions of Mormaer and of Toiseach"—were not likely to
return, in their own relations with their own Tenants, to the barbarous
customs whose very names had become words of opprobrium and reproach.
Accordingly we find that the Age of Charters in respect to Ownership was
also the Age of Leases, or other Covenants in respect to the Occupation of
land, so that all subordinate tenures tended more and more to be governed by
the same spirit of substituting limited and definite obligations for
liabilities which were always capable of unlimited extension, because they
were vague, unwritten, and undefined.
It may be well, however, to look
back a little here, to see, as we did in the case of Charters, what the
conditions of society seem to have been in the dark centuries, as regards
the cultivating class. Perhaps it would not be too much to say that during a
great part of those centuries there was no such class at all—except the
Monks and the Serfs. All other men lived mainly for war, or for the chase;
and even the Serfs must have had to bear their share in the work of
fighting, or of attending to those who fought. Agriculture cannot be a
pursuit except to peaceful men, and there were then no peaceful men except
the Christian Brotherhoods. Accordingly the earliest glimpses which we get
of agriculture in Scotland are connected with the landed possessions of the
Church. And one of the very first of these glimpses is in some ways the most
interesting of them all. In the narrative of the life led by St. Columba on
the Island of Iona, 1300 years ago, left us by the Abbot Adamnan, we see a
quiet picture of all the operations of a farm hardly differing at all from
those which constitute the ordinary operations of a modern farm, except that
they were more complete, and embraced a more varied provision for the
comforts of life. There was a Smithy for needed iron work. There was a Kiln
for the drying of corn. There was a Mill in which the Monks ground their own
corn into meal. There were cows and a co house or byre. There were
milk-pails carried from the pastures to the Monastery on horseback. There
was a Barn for the storage of grain. There was a Baker for baking the meal
or the flour into bread. Moreover, it is significant that this skilled
official was a Saxon. There were wheeled carts or carriages for the
conveyance of heavy articles. But these early ecclesiastical communities
worked the land themselves, or with the help of servants or bondmen. In
Iona, at all events, their land was too small in extent to induce them to
let out any part of it on hire.
But in this, as in all other cases, a different practice arose naturally
out of different conditions. The Church acquired in the Middle Ages more and
more extensive grants. That which conferred the island of Iona on Columba,
the great Missionary of the Sixth Century, was before the age of formal
Charters, and it seems doubtful whether it emanated from a King of the Picts
or of the Scots. But it is curious that the most ancient notice of it which
has come down to us lays special emphasis on the special feature of it
'which was novel at the time. That feature was the substitution of
"Definiteness" for "Indefiniteness" in the tenure which was asked and
given.' The Monks were wise enough to require something better than the
vague Tribal tenures which we have seen denounced by Sir J. Davies as common
among the Irish Celts.
And so throughout the Middle Ages the Church was,
as we have seen, the great civilising agency in establishing security of
tenure in the Ownership of land. We shall now see that the Church was the
great civilising agency, also, in establishing that other kind of security
of tenure which depended on written covenants and on calculated rents.
Ecclesiastics became the largest landowners in the kingdom, possessing
estates in many different districts— often at a great distance from the
Monastery. The lands so granted could not be wholly cultivated by their own
servants and bondmen as the few fields could be cultivated in the little
Island of Iona. Tinder such conditions it is easy to see how Tenancies
arose. For in principle there is no difference, and in practice there is a
natural and inevitable transition, between cultivators paid by food or wages
and cultivators paid by being allowed to retain a certain portion of the
produce. Nor, again, is the transition less easy or less inevitable from
this condition of things to that in which the cultivators undertake their
work for a definite term of years, and on definite conditions as to the
amount they are to pay in produce, or in the price of produce, or in
services, or (as was often the case) in all three forms of rent. In all
cases the essence of the transaction is the same. The Tenant gets from the
lord or Owner of the soil that one thing which he himself has not, and could
not otherwise get—namely, the assurance of full possession and of the sole
right to cultivate. This full possession and sole right to cultivate was to
exclude all other men. This exclusive possession was the one essential
element of the whole transaction; it was this for which the holder of it was
too glad to pay. In the enjoyment of it he was to be protected and defended
by the Owner whose alone it was, and who alone could lend it and assure it
to another. Very often the Owner gave or lent other things besides this. But
this exclusive enjoyment—this peaceful possession even when it stood
alone—was that for which the Tenant or holder was always willing to pay a
portion of the produce as its price or rent.
Very often—generally, indeed,
in very early times—when the actual cultivators were very poor, the Owner of
the land gave or lent something more than the mere possession of the soil.
He lent also the instruments of husbandry, and the cattle, sheep, or goats,
or other stock, which yielded perhaps the greater part of the whole produce
of the land. This is still the footing on which land is let in no small part
of Europe under what is now called the Metayer system, and which in Scotland
was at one time very common, under the name of "Steelbow." But with the
progress of wealth and of the population of free men, it became more and
more possible to let land on definite Leases to a class of cultivators
having sufficient capital of their own to furnish the necessary stock. The
transition, here, as in other cases, was natural and easy, since Leases had
been common under the Roman law, and the Ecclesiastics, who first made such
covenants, must have been more or less familiar with the customs of their
brethren in the south of Europe.
But as we had to go a long way back in
order to understand the language of the early Charters, so in like manner we
must go a long way back in order to understand the terms of the earliest
Leases. I have already alluded' to the various causes which had led among
the Celts to the same division between Freemen and Serfs or Bondmen which
had been equally established among the Teutonic races. Sentiment and poetry
combining, not with knowledge, but with the want of it, has been spreading
popular impressions on this as on other kindred subjects which represent
some great distinction between Scotland and England, and especially between
the Highlands and the Lowlands, in respect to the prevalence of Bondage. It
seems to be supposed that there were no Bondmen among the Celts as there
were in abundance among the Saxons. This is one of many similar delusions
which is at once dispelled by the slightest examination of the best
ascertained historical facts, and the most authentic documents. The earliest
Tribal laws and usages of the Celtic races, whether in Ireland, in Wales, in
Galloway, or in Scotland proper, are permeated through and through with the
precepts and principles of a rude jurisprudence founded entirely on lines
drawn between the Bond and the Free. The scale of fines for the murder or
homicide of the different orders and classes of society was a scale having
this great line of division as its base line. The scale of dues exacted by
the Chiefs upon marriages among the people subject to them, is also a scale
which was graduated upwards from the number of cattle due on the marriage of
the daughter of a Serf. For every word in the early Saxon language which
designates any due, or fine, or exaction of a rude and unwritten Feudalism
some corresponding word is to be found in the various dialects of the Celtic
language which prevailed over Ireland and Wales and Scotland.' How great was
the difference of value set upon the life of a Freeman, and the value set
upon the life of a Serf or Bondman among the Celts of Scotland may be
estimated by the fact that when David i. thought it expedient to give a
formal sanction to the customs of his Celtic subjects all over Scotland, he
thereby sanctioned a scale of fine for slaughter or homicide which ranged
between 1600 cows for a Prince, 100 cows for a Thane or Chief, down to 16
cows for the slaughter of a "Carl" or Serf. The "merchet" or due on marriage
of women showed less difFerenceas the scale ranged between calf and 12 cows.
Yet these most rude and unequal laws are specially recorded, not as the
relics of Saxon Serfdom, but as the then existing and living usages of the
Celtic races—the "Brettons" of Strathclyde and the "Scoti" in whom all the
Celts had been merged north of the Clyde and Forth. But one of the most
significant facts showing how much the poorer classes gained by the gradual
disappearance of Celtic customs in respect to Bondage, is this—that under
those customs it is evident that there had been established precisely the
same connection between Serfdom and particular areas of land which led to
such ruinous results in Prussia. In one of the fragmentary laws which have
been collected in the document called "Quoniarn Attachiamenta" there is one
which shows that the mere fact of a man, his son, and his grandson,
occupying certain portions of land which were known as "servile," and
rendering for it corresponding services, he and all his descendants to the
fourth generation became members of the servile class, and could be
adjudicated to be so before an assize court.
In all this we can trace a
steady stream of history running through several centuries from the wild and
rough hills of Celtic Feudalism into the rich and cultivated plains of
modern progress. We see passing before us the long series, and the gradual
current of events which prove that the Age of Charters and the Age of
Covenants, instead of having been times—as they are often ignorantly
represented—of the suppression of ancient liberties among the Celts, by the
introduction of foreign tyranny—were, on the contrary, times when the poorer
classes of the Celtic community were gradually but steadily delivered and
redeemed from very barbarous conditions, not only of Feudalism but of
servitude, which had grown up among themselves. When we think of the relics
and survivals of that barbarism which were still affecting widely and deeply
the condition of society in the Twelfth and Thirteenth Centuries, we must
estimate all the more highly those gentle but penetrating influences of
civilisation which were then sapping their foundations, and before which,
like snow before the breath of a southern air, they did within the next 200
years almost entirely disappear in Scotland. Moreover, we can see that it
was the Celtic race which most immediately and directly benefited by the
changes which were destroying Bondage. For they often remained as the poorer
and the working population of the greater part of the Lowlands and of the
eastern counties over the whole of Scotland, while the Ownership of the land
was passing steadily into the hands of Anglo-Saxon and Anglo-Norman Lords.
This fact is very clearly reflected in the early Charters and other
documents in which the regular word for the Serfs or Bondmen was the "Nativi,"
or old native Celtic population, whilst in some Charters they are called the
"Cumerlache"—a purely Celtic word which has been traced through the Irish
language to the term applicable to men who cultivated "servile land."
Moreover, in almost all cases in which individuals of this class are
mentioned in the Chartulanes, they are designated by Celtic names.
One of
the earliest steps which seems to have led to the elevation of this class
out of the ranks of Bondage, was a step which, at first sight, may seem to
have been in a backward rather than in a forward direction. This step was
the practice which seems to have been begun by the Monks of moving the
Bondmen from one estate to another for the sake of their labour in the
reclamation of land. " Chattel slavery" is associated in our minds with a
very inferior condition as compared with the old mediaeval Serfs who were "adstricti
glebrae"—transferable from one master to another only along with the land on
which they lived. And, no doubt, this would have been a backward step—if it
had stood alone—or rather if it had not stood in close connection with other
influences which gave to it a very different tendency. But when all those
other influences were moving in the direction of freedom, the mere breaking
of a bond which tied men to a certain locality was clearly in itself a gain.
If the spirit of the age was to make all dues of service more fixed and
definite—if service itself was coming to be measured by money payments—if
sale was already passing into hire,—it is clear enough that the
transferability of labour would be an advantage in itself.
This is another
of the innumerable cases in which the effect of any given social or
political change is entirely dependent on surrounding conditions. It is
curious to observe how completely unconscious those men were who began this
change, of the result to which it evidently contributed. They thought only
of the infraction it involved of ancient rights and usages—and they treated
it accordingly in a spirit of apology. Indeed they had to apply for special
permission to the Sovereign. All this appears very clearly in the earliest
documents we possess which record transactions of this kind. Thus we have a
special Ordinance or Prescript of Malcolm IV. (1153-1165), in which he gives
permission to the Prior and Monks of Coldingham to move "their own men,"
that is, their Bondmen, from the particular land on which they served to
Coldingbam, for the purpose of settling that Township.' The King forbids any
one to trouble them in this matter. So again in the Reign of Alexander ii.
we have the same Prior and Monks purchasing for 3 silver merks a Serf, with
his Sons and daughters, from a private landowner, who in his deed or note of
sale takes great care to plead that the transaction was one arising out of
his "great want."' And so again in another transaction of the same kind
between the same Monks and a different landowner, he explains in the same
spirit, that the price of 10 merks had been given to him "in his great
necessity."' On the other hand we have abundant evidence that the rigidity
of the old Celtic tie between the Bondman and the land on which he lived and
served, was being constantly broken from another cause. The Bondmen
themselves had an instinct in favour of free labour. In former times they
had often eagerly sought for the means of sustenance, and for the protection
which came with Bondage. But now they were perpetually escaping. "Fugitivi"
became one of the recognised names for them in numerous documents of that
age. Some of these documents are express mandates of the Royal authority in
favour of Monasteries entitling them to pursue and recover their fugitive
Serfs wherever they might be found on the lands of other men. Thus the same
Sovereign, Malcolm Iv. (1153-1165), whom we have seen giving to the Monks of
Coldingham the privilege of moving Bondmen from one estate to another, gives
to them also a Precept commanding all men that "wherever the Prior or his
servants can find fugitive Serfs justly belonging to Coldingham, they shall
have them justly, without disturbance or trouble, and I forbid that any of
you detain them unjustly."" Thus again in a later reign, that of Alexander
ii. (1214-1249), we have that Sovereign issuing a similar Precept in favour
of the Abbot of Scone, "or his serjeant," and in this case Serfs or Bondmen
are designated by their ancient Celtic designations of "Cumlaws and
Cumherbes," and they are described as "belonging to the lands of the Abbacy
of Scone."'
In all these transactions for the purchase of Serfs, and for
reclaiming them, the Abbots and Priors of these days were acting for the
best. Not only were they working hard at the Improvement of the Country, but
they were bringing the sweet influences of Christianity and the civilising
traditions of the Church to bear upon the relations between all those powers
which then represented Capital, and all those persons who then represented
Labour. Just as for centuries they had been the great instruments in
checking the exactions of" Mormaer and of Toiseach," so now they were not
less active in raising the condition of that lowest grade in Celtic society,
the "Cumlaws and the Cumherbes." When they got these Serfs into their
possession, they settled them on their lands with commutation and limitation
of the services which they had before been bound to render. The old
Columbite principle of changing the Indefinite into the Definite, which puts
an. end to so much that is picturesque and sentimental, but is nevertheless
the very foundation of everything that is civilised and free, was the
principle for which they worked, and which they gradually succeeded in
establishing.
On this subject we have some detailed and most interesting
information. The Rentals and the Journals of several of the Monasteries
during the Thirteenth Century have been preserved, and particularly those of
some of the great Monasteries of Teviotdale. Thus from the Rental of the
Abbacy of Kelso in 1290 it appears that all the agricultural class whom they
settled on their Estates, whether they had been Serfs or Freemen, were held
liable—not to "Cosherings" or "Cuttings" or "ilostings" or "Conveth" or "Caulpes,"
or any of the other old Celtic exactions, but to fixed rents in money,
together with services limited to a certain number of days, or to the doing
of certain definite things. Thus each Cottar paid from one to six shillings
a year, with services not exceeding nine days' labour. The tenants of
certain Crofts paid each two Bolls of meal, and were bound to shear the
whole corn on a particular set of fields. Again, on other holdings of a
large size, the tenants were bound to pay, Gs. Sd. of money rent, and to
render certain services in harvest, in sheep-shearing, in carrying peats and
wool, or in fetching the Abbot's commodities from Berwick. These
arrangements seem all to have been settled by mutual agreement and
stipulations, and they were so precise that they fixed even the services in
which the husbandman was to have his food from the Abbey, and those in which
he was to maintain himself.
Nor is this all. The same penetrating spirit
of reform, in substituting fixed dues for vague and semi- barbarous usages,
extended to every department in the management of their large estates. These
often included great extents of mountain-pastures which could only be grazed
by sheep. For these the Monks made careful arrangements as to folds, as to
huts or bothies for the herds, and as to shelter for the cattle. The
evidence of full and complete powers of property over the whole area, which
we have seen to be so striking in the wording of these Charters does not
rest on that wording only—but is equally confirmed by the daily life and the
multifarious transactions of estate management. The frequent transference of
lands from one Tenant to another - the settlement of disputed marches—and
the precision and care bestowed on Leases, show that the fundamental
conditions of all, agricultural improvement were being rapidly established
by the Monks, in the consecration of the freedom of labour, and of
corresponding freedom,—of order and legality —in the exercise of the fullest
rights of property.
When we consider the number of these Monasteries
which were founded in Scotland during the Twelfth and Thirteenth Centuries,
from the beginning of the reign of David I. in 1124 to the death of
Alexander III. in 1286, and when we consider further the ubiquity of their
landed possessions, both in the Lowlands and the Highlands, we may be able
to form some estimate of the influence they had in spreading everywhere the
same rules of conduct, and the same principles of law. There was no
difference whatever between the various parts of the Kingdom which were then
Celtic or non-Celtic in different degrees. Many parts of the country which
are purely Anglo-Saxon now were as purely Celtic then, whilst throughout the
districts which we now call Highland the great possessions of the Church
were universally managed on the same principles, and were directed from
local Monastic centres. Paisley had lands all through the Lennox and
Argyll;Scone and Cambuskenneth and Dumblane, through Strathearn and Menteith;
Dunkeld through the Central Highlands; Elgin and Inverness and Beauly
throughout the northern mountains, and all along the broad sea-margins of
the North-Eastern Coasts. And then, besides the lands held by the Monastic
bodies, the old Episcopal Sees of Scotland were endowed with large estates.
All of these exhibited the same principles of management, to which the old
native methods were all steadily conforming. So far from the native Celtic
population complaining of the full powers of Ownership exercised by the
Monks in the regulation of their estates,—so far from feeling this to be
harsh as compared with the older systems practised under their native Lords
and Chiefs,—that population, and every population brought into contact with
the Monasteries, were eager to come under their protection, and to exchange
the heavy and incalculable burdens of Celtic Feudalism for the moderate and
rational obligations which were founded on Covenant and on intelligible Law.
Part of the great benefits eagerly sought for by the people in coming upon
ecclesiastical lands depended, of course, upon the special privileges and
immunities of the Church from all the exactions which arose out of the
obligations of military service. But another part-----and a very great part
—depended on the fundamental change which lies in the passage from vague
unwritten customs to written agreements. And this unspeakable benefit
extended gradually but steadily, and on the whole rapidly, beyond the limits
of Church Estates. The Anglo-Saxon, and the Scoto-Norman Earls, and Chiefs
and Knights, imbibed the spirit of their age, and dealt with their Tenants
on the same principles on which they placed so high a value in their own
Charters from the King. The very word Charter has come to be associated in
our ears with the conceptions of security and of law. It was the Instrument
to which every Civic Community and every Owner of land equally looked as
their tower of defence against arbitrary Sovereigns. Just as every Burgh in
Scotland proceeded on the strength of it to develop its trade and commerce,
so, "armed with it, and supported by the law, Norman Knight and Saxon Thane,
and Celtic Chief, set himself to civilise his newly acquired, or his newly
confirmed property, settled his 'vii' or his 'town,' built himself a House
of Fence, distributed his lands among his own few followers and the "nativi"
whom he found attached to the soil, either to be cultivated on his own
account or at a fixed 'ferm' on the risk of the tenant."
Among the
historical facts which indicate this great line of advance in the path of
civilisation, one of the most interesting is that afforded by the
arrangements made by Alexander iii. for the marriage of his daughter the
Princess Margaret to Eric, the young King of Norway, in 1278. This was the
mother of the Princess whose early death subsequently gave rise to the
Disputed Succession, and ultimately to the War of Independence. Her portion
was to be 14,000 marks, but with an option to her father to give one-half of
this sum in Scotch Estates. Provisions of this nature of course implied a
well- known and ascertained relation between a definite extent of land and
its annual revenue; and this relation, again, could only be established on
the foundation of rents in money, or in produce commutable into money, which
were not dependent on vague customs or exactions, but upon Covenants and
agreements such as could be relied upon for a steady income.
Accordingly
we have historical evidence that these Covenants and agreements had been
embodied in the form of written Leases at a date almost as early as the
earliest Charters. One of the oldest upon record is dated 1190, and conveyed
the Tenancy of certain lands from a Lay Owner to the Abbacy of Kelso. The
system rapidly extended. Every kind and species of property came to be let
on hire for specific terms, and for specific rents—farms, mills, breweries,
houses with crofts, houses in towns, titles, annuities secured on rents,
dues, customs, and even the use of woods. In short, everything and anything
which men could own they could also either sell or let out on hire.' All
this came naturally, and as a matter of course. Such transactions arose and
multiplied with the security of property, the peace of society, and the
advance of civilisation. Towards the middle of the next century after the
earliest recorded Lease to the Abbacy of Kelso, in 1242, and again in 1296,
the lettings of land on Lease had become so common on Ecclesiastical Estates
that Provincial Councils of the Church. drew up canons on the subject,
having for their object to limit the duration of Leases granted to laymen to
the maximum of five years.
But although these and other transactions of a
similar kind make it evident that the system of letting land on hire for
definite rents had become well known and universally established long before
the close of the Thirteenth Century, it so happens that whilst we have many
much earlier Charters, no actual specimen of a written Lease has been
preserved which is dated earlier than the beginning of the next Century—the
Fourteenth. But this oldest specimen. is in the highest degree interesting
and instructive.
It is an agreement or contract between the Abbot of
Scone and two gentlemen, father and son, whose name was de Hay del Leys, for
the Lease of certain lands near Perth. The only peculiarity in the case is
that the Monastery of Scone had itself no chartered tenure of those lands.
They were held only at the pleasure of the King. It is evident that the
Monks considered this pleasure to be safe enough. But the possible
contingency of being deprived of it had to be contemplated and provided for
in the Lease. It is dated 1312—two years before the battle of Bannockburn.
In many ways this document is remarkable. In the first place, its
business-like and definite legal form indicates clearly enough that,
although it happens to be the first of these Covenants which survives, it
must have been drawn out on principles and on practices, if not in a form,
which had been long familiar. There could not be a better example of the
undivided powers then involved in the Ownership of land, and of the perfect
freedom which governed the relations between those who desired to let, and
those who desired to hire, the exclusive right of cultivation. Moreover, it
is remarkable in this—that the terms of the contract are in their nature
those which have come to be designated as an "Improvement Lease" —that is to
say, a Lease under the terms of which the Lessee was only too glad to
execute improvements upon the land, and to pay for, and out of, the
increasing produce some specified share of that increase in the form of
rent. He was not bound to improve, but it was assumed that he would do so
from self-interest. On this assumption he was bound to pay an increasing
rent—the steps of increase, however, being fixed and definite. In order to
pay this increase he would need to increase the produce. There was no other
compulsion in this particular case. But it was enough. In the loose language
of modern agitation the Tenant would have to pay this increase. "upon his
own improvements." But 574 years ago men understood the principles of
business better. The Tenants felt and knew that "their own improvements" had
to be made "upon," and out of, materials, and opportunities, and guarantees,
which were not "their own," but came from other men. All these came from the
Owner of the soil. They constituted a kind of Capital which the Tenants did
not possess, and it was in the nature of that Capital to - yield a very
large return to certain kinds of labour,—provided always, and provided only,
that the tenants got the assurance and security of posses- sion exclusive of
all other men. But this security and exclusiveness could only be got by
bargain with the Owners. Therefore the Tenants felt that their own
improvements could only be "their own" in part, seeing that another great
part of the result must be derived from, and be due to, the Owner. To him,
accordingly, the cultivating Tenants were always ready to render back in
rent some stipulated share of any resulting increase. In calculating what
that share might be, time was an all-important element. On the length of
exclusive enjoyment must depend the share of increased produce which could
be afforded. In, this case the term was for thirty years. The rent was to
begin at two merks for two years; to rise to three merks the third year, and
so on, one merk more for each year till the sixth. Then for the six
following years it was to remain at six merks—that is, until the end of the
twelfth year. Then for the eight following years to the end of the twentieth
year the rent was to be eight merks; and then for the ten remaining years of
the term it was to be ten merks. Besides this rent they were to grind their
corn at the Mill of the Convent, and to pay the usual dues on this necessary
service. They were to be at liberty to cut fuel (peat) on the farm ; but for
their own use only, and were strictly prohibited from selling it. The
Convent retained its right to pasture its cattle on the common grazing, and
to cut fuel on "the moors and marshes" when they shall have need. The
Tenants were further bound to build on the farm competent buildings for
themselves and their husbandmen, which they were to leave so built at the
end of their term; and, finally, in case of the Convent losing the land by
any revocation of the royal gift under which alone they held it, the Tenants
were held bound to leave the farm along with their Husbandmen, and with this
specified compensation, namely, the abatement of one year's rent for the
year in which they might be so dispossessed. But the teachings of this Lease
are so many and so important that, as in the case of the early Charters, I
think it best to present it to my readers in full :-
(Translation.)
AGREEMENT between the ABBOT OF SCONE and
EDMUND OF HAY DEL LEYS and WILLIAM, his
Son (1312).
IN the year of
grace 1312 was made this agreement between religious men. Lord Thomas by the
grace of God Abbot of Scone, and convent of the same place, on the one part,
and Edmund de Hay del Leys and William his son, on the other part, namely,
that
The said Abbot and convent have granted and to farm (rent) let all
their land of Balgarvi, with all pertinents, and their right marches,
With
which husbandmen were wont to hold the same land to farms (rent)
To the
said Edmund and William his son, and the heirs of the said William of his
own body lawfully, directly, immediately, lineally, and not collaterally to
be procreated, and descending until the term of thirty years following fully
complete.
Paying therefor yearly the said Edmund, William his son and the
heirs of the said William, to the said Abbot and convent, the first year two
merks of good and legal sterlings, namely, one-half at the feast of
Whitsunday, and the other half at the feast of St. Martin, in winter: the
second year, two merks at the terms before noted; the third year, three
merks; the fourth year, four merks; the fifth year, five merks; the six
year, six merks: and for the six years immediately following, namely, till
the end of the twelfth year, they shall pay six merks every year at the
terms before mentioned, and for eight years immediately following, viz.,
till the end of the twentieth year, they shall pay eight merks every year;
and for ten years immediately following, viz., till the end of the thirtieth
year, they shall pay ten merks every year of good and legal sterlings, at
the terms before noted.
The term of entry of the said Edmund and William
to the said land beginning at the feast of Whitsunday, the year of our Lord
1313; the term of their first payment beginning at the feast of Whitsunday
the year of grace 1313.
And the foresaid Edmund, William, and heirs of the
said William, shall do suit at the court of the Abbot three times in the
year, at the three head pleas, their husbandmen shall do suit at all the
pleas of the said Abbot, to be held within the barony of Scone.
And the
said Edmund, William, and heirs of the said William shall come to the Mill
of the said Abbot and convent of Kyncarroqui with all kind of corn growing
on the said lands of Balgarvy, which they shall grind for their sustenance,
and shall there give the twenty-fourth "vas" (peck) for all- saving the
right of those that serve at the mill (as knaveship):
And their men and
husbandrnen and their cottars shall give the sixteenth "vas" (= peck) of all
kinds of corn growing on the said lands of Balgarvi, as the other husbandmen
and natives of the said Abbot and convent:
Also both they and their
tenants shall do towards the preparation and upholding of the said mill in
all things as other husbandmen in the neighbourhood.
And the said Edmund,
William, and heirs of the said William, shall do the forinsec service of our
Lord the King so much as pertains to the said land, and they shall sustain
all other burdens in any manner of way touching the said land till the end
of their term foresaid.
And the said Edmund, William, heirs of the said
William, and their men dwelling on the said land of Balgarvi shall take fuel
from the common for their own use only, neither shall they sell therefrom,
give or alienate in any other way, unless from their arable land, which it
shall be lawful to them thence to take, give and sell.
Reserving to the
said Abbot and convent and their successors in the common pasture of the
said lands the usufruct for their animals; in moors and marshes for taking
fuel when they shall have need.
And if disputes, trivial and not grave,
shall arise among the men of the said Edmund, William, and the heirs of the
said William, they shall decide and correct them among themselves, but if
there shall be greater differences, and pertaining to the lordship, such
ought to be reserved for the court of the lord Abbot, there justly to be
determined:
Reserving in everything the lordship to the said lord Abbot:
And the said Edmund and William and heirs of the said William are bound,
without dissimulation, to agree to the counsel and assistance of the said
Abbot and convent when required.
And if our Lord the King shall happen to
revoke the gift of the said land from the said Abbot and convent, the said
Edmund, William, heirs of the said William, and their husbandmen, shall quit
without paying the rent of the year of their quitting.
And the said
Edmund, William, and heirs of the said William, shall cause to be
constructed on the said land of Balgarvi competent buildings for themselves
and their husbandmen, which they shall leave so built at the end of their
term.
In witness whereof . .
the common seal of the chapter of Scone is
appended, and the seals of the foresaid Edmund and William are appended.
This Lease exhibits all the essential features of the contracts between free
men for the hire of land which, down to our own time, have for the long
period of more than 550 years prevailed in Scotland, and which, the moment
domestic peace and security returned to any portion of the land, resulted in
an extent and a rapidity of agricultural improvement which has never been
surpassed in any country. The secret of the success of these. Covenants lies
in their definiteness, and with their definiteness, in their justice. The
particular stipulations might vary infinitely according to the nature of the
subject let. The term of years might vary from five to nineteen, or thirty,
or the term might be for a life, or lives. There might or there might not be
a bargain about improvements. It depended obviously on the cheapness or
dearness of the rent whether improvements would or would not be remunerative
within a given time, and without any other compensation than that secured by
the increased production arising out of them. This, too, was generally a
matter of express stipulation. In the Lease now referred to, the houses
built were to be left without any compensation. Probably the houses of that
time were made of turf and wattles. But in many other cases the Leases
provided for the payment of what were called "meliorations "—that is, for
the value of improvements of. a special kind. Sometimes they provided for an
optional "break" in the Lease at seven years, or some other period short of
the full term, and specified that the "meliorations" should be due to the
Tenant only if his enjoyment ended at the shorter term, and should be
extinguished if it lasted to the end. He could thus calculate securely how
far his outlay would he returned. Again, as regards another great source of
value in the Middle Ages—namely, dues in the form of labour—there might or
there might not be an exaction of services in labour, besides a rent in
money or in produce. But the one essential feature in all such lettings by
Lease was that every stipulation was as definite and precise as possible.
Both parties knew exactly what they were agreeing to. If services were
included, the amount and nature of the work to be done were generally
specifically mentioned. Already, in the previous century, the Thirteenth, we
find from the Rental of the great Abbacy of Kelso, that the Monks had
introduced the same principle of definiteness and precision into their
arrangements, even with their Husbandmen, who had no Leases, but who were
only Tenants at Will.
It is to be observed, however, that these Covenants
were strictly confined to the relations between the Owner and the Tenant,
or, as the Lease-holding tenant came to be called in Scotland, the "Tacks-
man,"—"Tack" being the name for a Lease. No notice whatever was taken in
most of these Leases of any class of men subordinate to the Lease-holder or
Tacksman. The full powers of exclusive possession for the purposes of
cultivation which the Owner enjoyed, as a necessary part of Ownership, were
lent or granted, on the stipulated conditions and for a given time, to the
Lessee who hired them. He had full power over all inferior or subordinate
occupiers, if any such existed. In the case of this earliest extant Lease,
given by the Abbot of Scone, we have some very clear and very interesting
intimations on this matter, which is one of the highest historical
importance. In the first place, we learn that the land or Farm which was
granted on Lease to Edmund and William de Hay del Leys had previously been
rented by Husbandrnen, or actual cultivators, who "were wont to hold the
same land to farms" (or rent). It is certain from this recorded fact, that
when these lands were granted to the Abbey, this grant (until revoked) was
not merely a grant of a rent charge, or a mere grant of grazing, but a grant
of such undivided Ownership as involved the right of the Abbot to re-let the
land to whom he would. The former "Husbandmen" were therefore not Serfs or
Bondmen, who were irremovable from the soil; neither were they free Tenants
with any rights of occupation which prevented the land being withdrawn from
them. In the second place, we see that the new Leaseholding Tenants were
expected, as a matter of course, to bring fresh Husbandmen of their own, who
are variously designated as "their men," "their husbandmen," and "their
Tenants." In the third place, we see that certain stipulations of the Lease
assume that over these men the Tacksmen had complete power to compel them to
pay certain services for the upholding of the Mill, and for the paying of a
higher rate of meal-tax for the grinding of corn than was to be paid by the
Tacksmen themselves. It appears further that this obligation in respect to
keeping up the Mill was a common obligation upon all the Husband- men of the
neighbourhood. Lastly, there is an express condition that the actual
Husbandmen or cultivators were to remove from the land along with the Tenant
himself at the termination of the Lease. This was evidently the common
practice and usual stipulation of that day. It was probably an absolute
necessity for the improvement of the soil then largely waste. The native
cultivators were probably then, as we shall see they were in much later
times, wedded to barbarous usages, or too ignorant and too poor to be
improvers. They might or they might not be mere servants or bondmen. They
were the "agricol" of the old Chroniclers, the "bondi" and "nativi" of the
earliest Feudal Charters. They were regarded as yearly tenants, and in the
eastern districts of Scotland they were often the remains of the old Celtic
population.' But, whatever their status was, whether bond or free, it is
clear that they were not recognised as then having, either by law or custom,
any right of occupancy in restriction or limitation of the full right of
Ownership. If they cultivated any land at all for their own use, which in
this case they were clearly expected to do, it must have been only as sub-
tenants at will of the "Tacksman" or Lessee, and as he could not give any
possession longer than his own, they were to leave the farm when he left it.
The power of sub-letting was itself generally a matter of express
stipulation. Sometimes it was specially allowed. Sometimes it was specially
prohibited. When there was no stipulation it seems to have been considered
as allowed.
There is one other stipulation of this Lease which
incidentally casts an important light on another question of much
interest—namely, the exact position under such Leases of the common grazings
of the country. We have seen that under the Charters special care was taken
to enumerate and include every variety and kind of surface—whether in woods,
or in mosses, or in meadows, or in mountain pastures. It followed as a
matter of course, and indeed of necessity, that when portions of such lands
were let, and divided from each other by definite "metes and marches,"
whether these were natural or artificial, the whole surfaces within those
marches were equally the subjects of the Covenant. The grazings, as dis
tinguished from the comparatively small areas of enclosed land, were often
the most valuable portion of the subjects let. They continued to be "common"
in one sense only—namely, that like all other pastures in that time, they
were used promiscuously by the Tenant and by all his Sub-tenants or
Husbandmen. But the Tacksman alone had the power of disposing of them, and
of regulating the use of them among his subordinates. So absolute and
exclusive was this power, that the Chartered Owner himself had no right
whatever to use those pastures after he had let them, unless by express
reservation in the Lease. Just as he parted with his exclusive right of
possession over the arable land in favour of his Lessee, so also did he part
with his rights of grazing, except in so far as by express stipulation he
might reserve a share. Hence the clause in this Lease which expressly
reserved to the Monastery their right to pasture their cattle upon the
common grazings of the farm of Balgarvie. The word "common" referred to the
method of use, not at all to the principle of tenure. It was assumed that
the Lessee would have as complete power to exclude the cattle of the Owner
as to exclude the cattle of all other men, unless the Owner took care to
preserve, or to reserve, some portion of his own rights in this matter.
At
this time, it is to be observed, the principles embodied in the Lease rested
on no special legislation, but on the much stronger foundation, first, of
the acknowledged rights involved in Ownership, as these had come to be
developed through the course of many centuries, and secondly, of the
correlative right of all Owners either to sell or to let their property to
any men, and on any conditions, whether of purchase, or of hire. All
Charters, as we have seen, had taken these rights for granted, and they had
grown up so naturally and so reasonably, and so much as a matter of
necessity, that they required neither definition nor support. Moreover,, it
is quite certain that as we have traced the spirit of precision which more
and more governed the form of Charters to the influence of the Latin Church
and the principles of the Roman Law, so it is even more certain that the
same spirit as applied to Leases was derived from the same copious fountain
of all the elements of Justice and of Civilisation.
Under the Republic
land was constantly let on hire, and the Contracts of Leases were among the
most familiar of all legal instruments. No actual copy has survived, but the
leading stipulations are accurately known. They regulated the rent, which
was fixed or definite, either in money, or in produce, or in service. They
regulated the duration of the tenancy, which was always definite also, and
often short—most commonly not more than five years. They regulated also the
devolution of the Lease to certain Heirs. They regulated, moreover, the kind
of husbandry and the succession of crops—so as to secure the Owner against
the losses which so often arise to Owners from the misuse of their property
by bad husbandry. They regulated also the power of sub-letting. There was,
in short, under the noble jurisprudence of the noblest people that have ever
ruled, perfect freedom of contract between Free Owners and the Free Hirers
of Land.
Under the Empire the number of Leases declined, because Freedom
declined also, and the number of Free Men. It had already become more and
more the custom to cultivate great estates by Slaves. They of course did not
hold under contract, nor were the dues they paid in the nature of a rent.
They were allowed to keep certain portions of the produce—enough to sustain
their life, and to suit their servile status; but nothing near the
proportion of the total produce which fell to the lot of Free Tenants under
the system of Covenants. More and more as the Free Population of Italy
became exhausted by constant and decimating wars, this system of great
extents of country cultivated by Slaves extended itself, and was the symptom
rather than the cause of evils which were sapping the foundations of the
Empire. It was to this system that Pliny referred when he spoke of "Latifundia"
as having "ruined Italy." By a most ignorant perversion of historical truth,
this passage has been quoted over and over again as applicable to large
Estates in modern Europe, and especially in Scotland. Yet the two systems of
management were not only different in their origin and in their nature, but
they were the antithesis of each other. Slavery never did exist in modern
Europe on the scale or of the character which prevailed in the Roman Empire.
There was, indeed, Serfdom and Bondage, and as we have seen there were a few
scattered and individual cases in which the sale and purchase of individual
Serfs with their families were just enough to show how easily under less
happy auspices the institutions of Serfdom might have passed into genuine
Slavery. But the line of movement in society was not towards the extension,
but towards the extinction of it. The greatest of all Landowners, as we have
seen, the Church, worked steadily against it. All other Landowners followed
in their wake, and before the end of the century in which the two Hays
received their Lease from the Abbot of Scone, Serfs and Bondmen had
practically disappeared from Scotland, and the system of free Tenants
holding under free Covenants had become the established usage of the
country.
Those who mistake or mis-state the facts on this great question
of the comparative extent and on the comparative character of Slavery in the
old Heathen and in the modern Christian world, are either ignorant or
careless of a distinction which is fundamental to all right understanding of
the history of Mankind. Some of those facts are indeed so strange to all we
have either seen or heard of since the Christian era that they seem hardly
credible. At least it is most difficult for us to realise the conditions of
society which are authentically known to have prevailed in the Roman Empire,
or even in the later days of the Republic. Slavery was at the root of
everything. It was the basis of society so far as all labour was concerned.
Some rich men possessed as many as 20,000 Slaves, the majority of whom were
Field Labourers. Crassus is said to have had 500 "head" alone as his corps
of builders and carpenters. Slaves are said to have been as three to one of
the whole free population at the opening of the Christian era, and for 200
years later. So early as the times of the Gracchi they were displacing the
free rural population, whether small proprietors or free labourers. Nor did
this great curse affect the rural districts only. Freemen were crowded out
of the Towns, as well as out of the fields, by swarms of Slaves. Their
labour was displaced, and their number diminished. Little more than a
century after the death of Pliny, agriculture had so declined that Italy
could no longer support its own population, and the Emperor Commodus
organised a regular fleet of vessels so large as almost to correspond to our
modern idea of a "Liner," by which the harvests of other lands might be
carried to the Tiber. Rome came to be supplied in abundance with corn from
Carthage and from Alexandria, from Palermo and from Cadiz, and from all the
ports of the world accessible to the great grain ships—from 1000 to 1300
tons burden—which were employed in the trade. The free farmers and free
labourers were thus undersold from abroad, whilst at the same time they were
undersold at home by the cheap labour of slaves who were exempt from
military service. These were spread over large tracts of country. The free
population disappeared. This was the cause, and this was the nature of the
evil which was denounced in the word "Latifundia." The most learned man,
perhaps, now existing in Europe has examined this subject with the
conscientious care which is always equal to his great resources. He shows
how Slavery had undermined Freedom not only by way of the displacement of
labour, but by way of the corruption of opinion. Even in the mind of such a
man as Cicero, it had stamped as servile and unworthy a multitude of
employments, which in themselves are as noble as any other forms of
industry. "It was thus," says Dr. Dollinger, "the sturdy, industrious middle
class was lost to Rome. The free population consisted of proletarii, living
in republican times by the sale of their votes, and under the Emperors upon
the public distribution of money and corn; degraded and demoralised they
were despised by the rich and assimilated more and more to Slavery. . . .
The Roman people was, though Slavery diminished, depraved, and utterly
changed to its heart's core. The genuine plebeian stock had in reality
ceased to exist. Already by 150 B. C., Scipio iErnilianus had taunted the
grumbling populace with the assurance that he should never tremble before
those whom he had himself brought in chains to Rome. It was not the 'Latifundia,'
as Pliny thought, but Slavery that had ruined Italy: had the Latifundia been
peopled by Free Tenants the consequences would have been different."
This difference between the Roman Slaves and the Free Tenants of modern
Europe is a difference indeed. To confound the Latifundia of Pliny's time
with the great Estates of Medieval Barons is a blunder which is excusable in
platform orators, to whose speeches the quotation of one Latin sentence
gives a tinge of learning. But it is inexcusable in men who care for sound
reasoning, or for the truth of History. In no part of modern Europe did the
evils of the Roman Latifundia arise. In no part of it were they even
possible. But in Scotland perhaps more than in any other country, the
holders of great Estates at this time were the Leaders of the Nation not
less in the progress of civilisation than they had been in winning National
independence. It has been well said both of the New Owners and of the Old
Owners with a new title, that they were of the progressive party. Their own
interests, their own powers, their own aspirations—all combined to make them
so. Their territorial possessions could not be used except by sharing them
with others. Parts they granted in "Feu-farm" to kinsmen, to friends, and to
retainers. Parts they let to Tacksrnen on different conditions of Lease. On
parts they kept the native Husbandmen, supplementing their resources by
lending them seed, cattle, and other stock; whilst again other portions of
their land they cultivated themselves by hired labourers. The whole of these
were Free Alen, constituting a gradation of classes, founded on free dorn,
and manly dealings with each other between diverse ranks. All this was the
very converse of the processes and causes which ruined Italy. The nearest
type and image of them in the world which arose on the ruins of the Roman
system, is to be found not in the great Baronies or Estates which were
chartered with us in the Twelfth and Thirteenth Centuries, but in the
territories which were then still subject to those unwritten usages of
Celtic Feudalism which Chartered rights of Ownership had happily superseded.
That older and ruder Feudalism had been from the beginning largely founded
upon Bondage, and it still subjected men who were nominally free to
arbitrary exactions, so vague, so various and so enormous, that it was
impossible to calculate on the secure enjoyment of the fruits of industry.
The change which took place in the passage from these usages to such written
Covenants as that which we have examined, was a change as deep and searching
as it was beneficent.
Accordingly we find that everywhere over the whole
of Europe the influence of the Latin Church led to a return to those better
and earlier practices of the Roman people which consisted in the letting of
land to Free Tenants under Covenant, and which had never ceased to be
recognised and sanctioned under their noble jurisprudence. Probably even in
the worst of times it had never wholly ceased, for there must have been many
places and many circumstances in which Slaves could not be found, or could
not be trusted to be the sole cultivators of landed property—especially when
that property lay in distant Provinces of the Empire. Thus we know that the
Sicilian Estates of the feeble Rulers who still represented the Western
Empire among the marshes of Ravenna, were, in the middle of the Fifth
Century, let to Free Tenants on Leases with all the definite covenants usual
in modern Estates.' As we advance towards the Middle Ages, we see that the
Lessees of all ecclesiastical lands were generally free cultivators; and
towards the end of the Thirteenth Century we have a French Treatise on the
customs of a portion of that country, from which it appears that lands were
let under precisely the same word used in Scotland about the same time—
namely, the word "ferme"—meaning a fixed rent agreed to upon a series of
fixed conditions.' In Germany the progress of events was not so steady in
this direction. Serfdom lasted longer. There were stupid and antiquated
limitations of land to particular classes, and there was a fatal preference
of old usages, which are always tending to abuse, over perfect freedom and
definite agreements between free men, which are always open to re
adjustment. These were undoubtedly among the causes which led to the fall of
Prussia. She did not recover till means had been taken to abolish the abuses
of a traditional and unwritten Feudalism. And it is remarkable that when
Stein was studying the reforms which he afterwards promoted, he took as his
model, and as the goal at which he aimed, those happier developments of
Feudalism under Anglo-Saxon and Scoto-Roman law which he saw established in
Great Britain.
We strike deep, then, into the very roots of modern
history, and into the very sources of our civilisation, when we examine all
that is implied in this Lease given by the Abbot of Scone in the earliest
years of the reign of King Robert the Bruce. Like the Charters it may be
said that Leases rose out of the ground, and grew. They were far more deeply
founded than on any local legislation. They sprung from the seeds of
freedom, sown in the fruitful soil of Roman Law, and trained, as regarded
their form and development, under the conscientious direction of the Latin
Church. Nay, it may even be said with truth that the original source of
these Covenants lay deeper still. For the foundations of morality are the
common property of all mankind. The obligation of a promise is an elementary
obligation. The faith of Covenants is universally recognised as a faith
which cannot be denied. Strange to say, the value of it to society has never
been more picturesquely or forcibly described than by the oldest known code
of Celtic Laws. For in the "Brehon Laws" we are told that "there are three
periods at which the world is worthless: the time of a plague, the time of a
general war, the dissolution of express contracts."
Sir Henry Maine has
referred with some incredulity to this sentence as seeming very like a later
introduction.' In this I venture to disagree with him. The whole method of
expression is thoroughly Celtic. The words translated "express contracts" do
not accurately convey the meaning of the original, and might suggest to our
ears the idea of written documents. This would indeed savour of a later
age,—of formal "deeds" and parchments. But the Celtic words here used are
full, on the contrary, of that archaic time when there was nothing more
binding than the spoken word—the promise of the mouth,—accompanied or
unaccompanied by some symbolic act. Accordingly, the Celtic words used in
this passage of the Brehon Laws, which have been rendered by the English
words "express contract," specify the method of expression as the oral
method—" contracts made by word of mouth." I find, moreover, that there are
some idiomatic phrases in the Scottish Gaelic in which the same word "Cor"—not
now in common use—is still retained as expressive of a possessory right in
the strongest possible sense. A Highlander will say, pointing to something
which he thinks belongs to him, "that is cor to me," meaning, "that is my
right." The whole passage, therefore, instead of having a modern aspect, is
redolent, on the contrary, of very archaic times. There can be little doubt,
indeed, that those who wrote it were not thinking of Covenants about what we
call the hire of land. But there can be just as little doubt that they were
thinking, and must have had familiarly in their minds, Covenants about the
possession of cows, and about the grazing of them, and about the division of
their calves, and about the sharing of their milk, and generally about the
services which men were willing to promise to each other, for any and every
kind of benefit rendered to themselves. All this is the same thing. Just as
cattle stood in the place of capital in those early days, so did they stand
in the place of farms, and all bargains between man and man about them were
fundamentally the same as the bargains which were made in later times about
the share of cattle, or of other produce which was commuted into various
forms of rent. The introduction of this passage, therefore, into the Brehon
Laws does not necessarily indicate, or even naturally suggest, any foreign
element other indeed than those earliest echoes of Celtic Christianity in
which we hear the missionaries of the New Testament repeating and enforcing
the divine teachings of the Old.' In the writings of the Jewish Prophets we
see always the same conception—that the mouth is the organ of the mind and
heart in their deepest issues of Thought and of Intention. The solemn
promise—the sacred vow—is always spoken of as recorded by the lips. Thus
amid the splendours of the sixty-sixth Psalm we have the words—"I will pay
Thee my vows which my lips have uttered, and my mouth hath spoken, when I
was in trouble." And so also, in respect to the great duties of Worship and
Devotion the "fruit of the lips" is spoken of as our truest and most
acceptable oblation. Such are the real fountains of the fine old proverb in
the Brehon Laws which ranks the breaking down of personal honour and good
faith in the keeping of engagements as among the heaviest calamities of
mankind. This is its true connection; for the same passage goes on to
represent the great practical duties of Charity and of Religion as the best
guarantees against the three enumerated evils. And when it is added that
these duties "confirm all in their good contracts and in their bad
contracts," we recognise the influence and authority of that grand
Benediction in the Psalms of David, which is pronounced upon him "who
sweareth to his own hurt, and changeth not."
The Covenants, however, about
the hire of land, of which we have thus seen the first example, did not need
the exercise of any heroic virtue. Men did not make them to their own hurt,
but, on both sides to their own advantage. The silence of their
introduction, the speed of their advance, and the universality of their
prevalence, are all consistent, and consistent only with the knowledge, and
experience of mutual profit, or mutual convenience. And as in all other
similar cases where the growth of individual interests is founded on rules
of law becoming more and more definite and precise, these Covenants tended
directly and very powerfully to the growth of national prosperity and
wealth. The feelings and the instincts which inspired these Covenants are
the real explanation of their great results. Sentiment underlies all conduct
and all opinion; and the prevailing sentiment of any given time is that
which directs for evil or for good the working of its practices and its
laws. If that sentiment be natural unperverted, the working will be of a
corresponding character. If it be corrupt, or even if it be only rude and
barbarous, its working will inevitably lead to corruptions far deeper than
its own. For this is the nature and property of all evil in man and in
society—to lead further and further from the ascending path, by the downward
steps of Natural Consequence. Thus the prevailing sentiment which has been
common in many early conditions of society that war is the only occupation
worthy of a man, and that all forms of industrial labour are comparatively
mean, is a sentiment which has always been damaging, and very often has been
absolutely fatal. Wars when waged for a noble cause have an ennobling effect
on men. The mere love of fighting and of rapine has, on the contrary, an
effect the most degrading. Nor is this effect redeemed by picturesque
stories and martial poetry, whether they be Norse Sagas, or Gaelic songs. We
have seen that the Celts under Robert Bruce were disciplined like other
civilised men to fight in the very van of great battles for great national
objects. But the prevailing sentiment of society in Scotland in his days,
and in the old times before them, was what may be called, shortly, the
Spirit of Improvement. As one Province after another was cleared of an
enemy, and firmly added to the Kingdom, the next thing thought of was always
to settle and improve it, by giving it to men who could hold it in security,
and could reclaim it from bog or forest by their own servants, or by letting
it out to Husbandmen. These classes moved and were moved freely from one
Estate to another as their services or their undertakings were required. The
sentiment of keeping men on the soil for the sole purpose of fighting for a
bare living, eked out by raids and forays, was not the sentiment of the
Kingdom or of the people in those greatest days of our national history.
Robert the Bruce did indeed enact, in a Parliament held at Scone in 1318,
that all men should be armed according to their rent or possessions—the
humblest being bound to provide himself with at least a good Spear or a good
Bow and one sheaf of (24) Arrows. But he and his predecessors were equally
desirous that, when possible, the Sword should be turned into the
Ploughshare and the Spear into the Pruning--hook. For this purpose they
encouraged peaceful industry, and the movement of the cultivating classes
from one district to another, as the great work of reclaiming a wild country
might require, under the operation of natural motives and of free Covenants.
Accordingly we have historical evidence that such movements of the rural
population were constant and habitual, and that they began far earlier than
is generally supposed. The provisions of the Scone Lease in 1312 show that
one set of Husbandrnen went out when the new "Tacks- man" came in, whilst
another set came in with him when he entered, and were required to leave
with him when he left. But this bit of evidence stands halfway in point of
time between two other items of evidence to the same effect. One of these
comes from the century before the Scone Lease, and the other from the
century after— showing that we have in the Scone Lease an example of the
regular rule and practice of a long and a great Age. More than a hundred
years before that Lease, so early as 1209, in the Reign of William the Lion,
we find that the case of Husband- men leaving their holdings at the
covenanted expiration of an express term, had become a case so common that
it needed special notice and recognition in respect to the heavy dues which
were then raised on the grinding of corn for the support of Mills.
Accordingly it was provided in a short Act of the Great Council of the
Kingdom, held at Scone in 1209, that a man leaving land which he had held on
Lease for a given term, "and passing away," should not be called upon to pay
more than a certain limited rate of "multure" on his corn, or should, have
one half of the quantity required for seed wholly exempted.' Another Statute
of the same date made some corresponding regulation for the case of new or
in-coming Tenants. This early care for "outgoing Tenants," and for those who
came in their place, as a well-known class, is remarkable. We are apt to
fancy that in those remote times agriculture was hardly yet a profession or
a pursuit—that men only farmed to live, and that there were few or none who
lived to farm. But from this old law of William the Lion, and from the
simple and natural terms in which it speaks of a class who held lands "on
farm," and who "passed away" from them at the end of their term, it is clear
that this condition of things had then already become common at the
beginning of the Thirteenth Century, and that all the Estates of the Realm
regarded it as a natural and necessary incident of the progress of
agriculture, and of the operation of free Covenants between those who owned,
and those who hired land for the purposes of cultivation. Such movings and
changings among Tenants might arise either from the Tenant thinking he could
do better elsewhere, or from the Owner finding he could do better in
improving and reclaiming through other men.
We have only to look at the
Scone Lease to see how great was the work, of reclamation in those days, and
how little it could be intrusted to men who mentally, if not physically,
were "adstricti glebce," tied by ignorance to the idle habits and wasteful
usages of a barbarous age, who had absolutely no capital, or whose industry
had often been destroyed by the desolating customs of Celtic Feudalism.
There was much to be done in those days in subduing the earth, and it was
the first care as it was the first duty of the Owners of land to see that
those things were done. How much was expected from, and how much was
habitually done by, the class of men who took land on hire, and who
reclaimed it for their own profit, as much as to the advantage of the Owner
and of the Nation, may be judged by the scale of increasing rent which was
bargained for by the Monks under the Scone Lease. Within the comparatively
short space of 20 years, the Tenants in this case became bound to pay ten
merks instead of two merks for the same amount of land. That is to say, that
the calculated increase of value, measured by rent alone, was to be 500 per
cent. Beyond all this, of course, the Lessees expected to make not only a
profit, but probably an increasing share of profit out of the reclamations
they might effect. But assuming that their profit was to bear to the end of
the Lease, not an increasing proportion, but only the same proportion to
total produce as at the commencement, we see that the processes of
improvement were then known to be so rapid and so sure in their results that
Lessees could calculate upon a great increase of produce in twenty years,—so
great that a Farm producing corn and cattle to the value of 6 merks, at the
beginning of that time, was safe to produce at least 30 merks' worth at the
end of it. I assume, as a rough approximation to the truth, the correctness
of an old saying in Scotland, that Rent in those days generally represented
about one-third of the produce. This saying was embodied in a rhyme which
has descended with its old Scotch dialect from distant generations,-
"Ane to saw,
Ane to maw,
And ane to pay the Laird witha'."
which,
translated into purer Anglo-Saxon, means "One part to sow (for seed), one
part to eat (consumption or profit), and one part to pay the Laird (Owner)
withal" (Rent).
There is no reason to believe that the rate of increase
contemplated under the Scone Lease was in any way exceptional, for fertile
as the Valley of the Tay now is, it is clear that at that time it had a
large proportion of peat-mosses and other wild land, which, under the system
of Free Covenants, already long in operation before 1312, have now entirely
disappeared.
I have already said that the Scone Lease stands midway in
point of time between two items of historical evidence as to the habitual
movings and changes among the cultivating class, consequent on the taking
and on the leaving of land under covenants of Lease. We have seen how
distinct that evidence is at a date more than a hundred years before the
Scone Lease. Let us pass on for another hundred years, and we have another
evidence still more emphatic and remarkable. It is, indeed, a most
significant indication of the fundamental value attached to the full rights
of Ownership in land, and of the insuperable objections which were then
entertained against any division of those rights or any limitation of them
except such as might flow from perfect freedom of contract between free men.
This indication is afforded by an entry in the proceedings of one of the
early Parliaments of James i. held at Perth in the year 1429—an entry of a
most anomalous kind. It appears that the system of letting land on lease to
"Tacksmen" had become so prevalent that attention had been much called to
the consequent sudden removal of the actual cultivators or Husbandmen who
had previously occupied the lands so let James i. did not ask his Parliament
to remedy this inconvenience by giving to such cultivators any "fixity of
tenure" which would be obviously incompatible with undivided Ownership and
with the progress of agricultural improvement. He did not even ask therefore
for any positive statute on the subject. But he proposed to, and obtained
from, the Barons and Prelates who were the great Landowners present at
Perth, a promise or engagement that for the future they would give one
year's notice to all cultivators or Husbandmen whose removal might be
involved in any new Leases they might grant.' At a time when there was much
un cultivated land, and no difficulty in obtaining the occupation of it,
this promise was probably quite effectual to prevent any serious hardship to
the cultivating class.
It is not, however, till twenty years later that we
find the earliest legislative landmark in the history of Covenants for the
hire of land. The first Act of Parliament on the subject arose out of the
necessity of deciding whether the Owner of land could grant Leases which
should be binding on his successors by purchase, or on other "singular
successors;" that is, successors to the estate not being his own natural
heirs. The question before that old Parliament may be stated thus:—each new
Owner, in buying land, bought or succeeded to all the full rights of
Ownership. Could he be deprived of them by the act of those who had preceded
him? To admit that he could was in one sense an immense extension of the
powers of Ownership, because it extended those powers even beyond the grave,
and made the "dead hand" prevail over the living. Yet, in another sense, and
for the very same reason, it would be a great limitation on the powers of
Ownership in the hands of the living, because it made them subject to
promises and engagements to which the living Owner had never been a party.
Whether was the dead Owner or the living Owner to prevail? Were all existing
and living Owners to be deprived of their freedom over their own estates
because their predecessors had chosen to limit their own freedom during
their own lives? This was one aspect of the question, and it was the aspect
in which the question might most naturally be regarded by an Assembly of
rough Chiefs and Barons, who were themselves also the greatest Landowners in
the Kingdom.
But there was another aspect of the question —namely, this:
What was just to those who had taken Leases from one Owner and found
themselves suddenly in the hands of another? Again: What was the best
principle to adopt in the permanent interests of agriculture and of all the
classes who had interests in land subordinate to the interests of Ownership?
These were the questions which had to be decided by the Parliament of
Scotland in 1449; and the manner in which they were decided is an excellent
answer to the ignorant claptrap which assumes that all ancient legislation,
having been enacted by the classes connected with the Ownership of land, was
necessarily guided by purely selfish spirit. It would be more true and
philosophical to admit that, on the whole, in every advancing country, each
generation has had at least as much conscience and as much sense of justice
as our own. So it was certainly in the Fifteenth Century in Scotland; and,
although in that case, as in all other similar cases, the decision which was
just was also, in the long-run, the decision most conducive to the interests
of those who might have been tempted to think otherwise, yet the reasons
which influenced that decision were reasons of conscience dictating a wise
and reasonable policy.
It is, indeed, remarkable that these
considerations, and not what we should now call reasons of Political
Economy, are especially set forth in this statute, as the determining
considerations in the case. The wording is curious :-
"It is ordained for
the safety and favour of the poor people that labour the ground that they,
and all others, that have taken or shall take lands in time to come from
Lords, and have times and years thereof, that suppose the Lords sell or
alienate these lands, the Takers shall remain with their tacks on to the
ische (expiry) of their times, into whosesoever hands these lands come
(pass), for such like male (rent) as they took them for before."
This is indeed sound, wise, and civilised legislation—directed to the
encouragement of deliberate contracts by insisting on their binding force
against the party which was then the strongest—and on their binding force,
too, especially in the case of a change of Ownership, so that Leases should
be valid against all comers. It has been supposed that the words" poor
people that labour the ground" indicate some very specially low condition of
the agricultural classes. But this is by no means a ne'cessary implication.
It does, indeed, imply that Leases were given to Tenants who were poor. But
the protection which the statute gives is not confined to this class, but is
expressly extended to "others "—to all who, whether poor or comparatively
rich, should make bargains for the hire of land for definite times and for
fixed rents. The historian is right when he describes this law as "a wise
and memorable act in its future consequences on the security of property,
the liberty of the great body of the people, and the improvement of the
country."
It will be observed that this legislation not only places no
restriction on the undivided Ownership of land, but that it implies and
assumes as belonging to that property the most complete and unrestricted
rights. It was simply an Act to facilitate and to enforce contracts or
engagements which had been deliberately made. As between the Owner and the
Lessee it implies that the Lessee could have no other rights than those he
might stipulate for in his Lease. He could enforce these, not only against
the natural heirs and successors of the Owner with whom he had made the
covenant, but also against all who might otherwise acquire the same estate,
but beyond these he had none to enforce. He was in no way protected against
himself. He might agree to render services of any extent, but they must be
sufficiently definite to be capable of legal enforcement.. On the other
hand, neither in this way nor in the way of rent in money or in produce
could the Owner add anything during the stipulated term. But again, at the
end of that term all the Lessee's rights ceased, because this was part of
the covenant. Thus both parties could have confidence —that one essential
element in all the transactions of business. Then, further, as between the
Lessee and those under him there was no interference of the law. The Lessee
could exercise all the rights of Ownership which his Lease conveyed to him,
and if there was no Lease or other express Covenant, the law presumed him to
have the yearly fruits of the soil, whether natural or artificial, and the
complete power of exclusive occupation over the whole surface for the
purposes of husbandry.' If his Lease allowed him to sublet, he might do so
under whatever conditions he could obtain from others. If his Lease did not
allow him to sublet, the prohibition would be enforced. If the Lease was
given to a group of the "poor people that laboured the ground," the same
rights and obligations applied to them that applied to the wealthier
individual "Tacksman." Such men who held land under Lease could deal with
all others of their own class precisely as richer Lessees could deal with
them under the same conditions. The one great characteristic feature of this
system, and its one immense superiority over Celtic and all other mere local
customs, was in the substitution of certainty for uncertainty, of
Definiteness for Indefiniteness, of known and settled law for mere vague
usages and tradition.
We pass on for another short space of only 20 years,
and we come upon another sample of that wise and progressive legislation
which, in keeping to fundamental principles, and to all that was good in
ancient usages, yet took note of evils as they arose, and checked any
accidental invasions of acknowledged obligation. Somehow it had come to pass
that when Owners of land got into debt, their creditors came upon their
lands and seized all the cattle and crop they could find upon it, without
distinguishing between that which properly belonged to the Owner of the
soil, and that which belonged to the hirer of it. Probably this hardship
began in and arose out of the prevalence of "Steelbow" holdings, in which
the cattle and other stock were supplied by the Owner of the soil. But
whatever was its origin, it had become a grievance, and it was obviously
destructive of the principle of a Lease, which secured the Tenant against
any increase of his "male" or rent before the expiry of his term. If a
Tenant had this security only against a solvent Owner, but lost it as
against creditors the moment his landlord became insolvent, it is obvious he
would practically have no security at all, and the whole value of Leases
would have been destroyed. Accordingly, in strict consistency with the
fundamental principle of ancient and well-established covenants, with recent
confirmatory legislation, and with the clear equities of the case, the
Parliament of James iii.' which was held at Edinburgh in 1469, enacted, that
this invasion of the faith of Leases should he put an end to—that the "puir
tenants" should never in any case be liable for any portion of their
Landlord's debts, beyond the amount of their stipulated rent so that "the
inhabitants should neither be grieved nor hurt by their Lord's debts." The
Roll of this Parliament shows that only four Burgesses attended,
representing Stirling, Aberdeen, Edinburgh, and Dumfries. All the rest of
the legislative body belonged to the Ecclesiastical and Baronial Orders
—who, in this case, as usual, were the leaders of the nation in the progress
of civilisation and of law.
There is but one other important step to be
noticed in this memorable course of legislation. Eighty-five years later
than the Statute we have just mentioned, it was again found necessary for
Parliament to interfere for the purpose of regulating the forms under which
Owners should give notice to Tenants whether they intended to renew their
Covenants for another term or not. Some ancient traditional customs
connected with this point are curious and obscure. It seems that in remote
times, before written documents were in use, the Owner of land, in letting
it to a "Malar" or Tenant, used to present him with a wand. And so also when
he wished his "Malar" or Tenant to remove at the stipulated end of his term,
the Owner used to give him legal and formal notice by coming to his Tenant's
door, and breaking another wand before him.' And this could be done at any
time, and on any day in the last year of the Lease. This was clearly the
survival of some very ancient symbolism. I do not know its origin, and very
probably this cannot now be traced. But it points beyond question to the
great antiquity of the sentiment that the letting of land was a mere lending
of it by the Owner, and that he had a right to resume his property by a very
simple and peremptory process. In very rude and early times, when the stock
was very generally lent by the Owner along with the land itself, and when
Tenants had little or nothing to remove, except their persons and a few
simple instruments of husbandry, the want of any fixed period of previous
notice was probably not felt as a hardship, or even a serious inconvenience.
But of course as agriculture improved, and as the class which lived on the
hire of land became a little wealthier, this inconvenience would become
serious. It was to remedy this that a new Act was passed by the Parliament
of Queen Mary which sat in Edinburgh in 1555. There was evidently much need
of some processes more regular than those then in use, for we know by a
previous Act passed in 1546 that serious troubles and even bloodshed had
arisen connected with the removal of Tenants at the end of their Leases. The
Scottish Parliament did not conceive that the way to remedy such evils was
to sanction bad faith, or to legalise the breach of deliberate covenants.
But it did require that every step should be taken in due form of law—not by
sudden violence on the one side provoking as sudden resistance on the other,
but by the intervention of the King's Officers and the King's Courts. And
now for further and more permanent remedy, it provided that not less than 40
days' notice before Whitsunday in the last year should be given to every
Tenant if his Owner desired him to remove at the originally stipulated date.
If this notice was resisted, the case was to be taken before the King's
Courts, by whom the question was to be decided according to covenant and to
law.' Such has been the law of Scotland until the other day, since which a
larger notice,—the natural agricultural unit of one year, has been required.
The progress of agriculture has made this extension as reasonable as was the
period of 40 days in the Sixteenth Century. But practically that Statute of
Queen Mary may be said to have closed the era of Legislation. Upon that
Legislation, or rather upon the fundamental principlesof equity and of
acknowledged obligation which underlay it, the whole subsequent progress of
agricultural industry was conducted. It well fulfilled the noble purpose and
declaration which was made by one of the Parliaments of Robert the Bruce:
"The King wills and commands that common law— that right—be done to Poor and
Rich, after the old laws and freedoms before these times rightiously oysset
and hantit" (known and understood).
We have not yet done, however, with
the important historical questions on which light is thrown by the Scone
Lease. A common impression prevails in many minds, that although lands were
let on hire so early and so commonly as we have seen, yet that the rents
paid by the Tenants, if not mere quit rents, were at least very low, and not
at all regulated by anything like what we now understand by Market Value. It
is not easy to explain how this impression has arisen. In two ways the
evidence seems to be complete against it. The first kind of evidence is such
as that which arises out of the Scone Lease—going as it does to show that
rent was expected to follow the rising value of the land, and that Covenants
were habitually made under which the Lessee bound himself to pay increasing
rents, only, however, to a specified amount, as he might be enabled to pay
them out of increasing produce. The second kind, of evidence is not less
strong,—consisting in the fact that there were some Tenants to whom Lands,
Mills, Houses, and other subjects were let specially and expressly on the
footing that they should hold these various possessions at a low or
preference rent; and in the further fact that this was a well-known kind of
Lease, and a well-known class of Tenant, so well known, indeed, that they
were designated by a name separate from all others. This name, moreover, was
one singularly expressive of the special origin and of the special nature of
the tenure. In the language of those centuries they were "kindly Tenants."
This exactly signifies the exceptional personal feeling which led Landowners
from time to time to grant to particular persons, and as a particular favour,
farms or other kinds of holding at a low, or sometimes even at a nominal
rent— just as they might, and often did, actually for similar reasons, grant
Annuities out of rents or Feus at a small and fixed rate of Feu-duty.
Sometimes we know that these "kindly" feelings and kindly grants were given
in gratitude for some special service—sometimes to men of Knightly rank,
sometimes to Husbandmen, and "Nativi" of the country. But the same healthy
usages and laws which demanded " definiteness" in all other tenures, made
the same demand, and all the more carefully, in the case of this exceptional
kind of Tenancy. They were grants, or they were covenants, and nothing more.
Like all other grants and Covenants they must rest on evidence of the
intention of the Owner or the Superior from whom they came. The slovenly
argument or inference that, because an Owner may not have asked a higher
rent for a long time, he had thereby parted with his right to do so, and had
sacrificed a power incident to Ownership, was an argument never used, and an
idea never entertained, in those days. But on the other hand, in the high
spirit of legality and precision, which is the only secure defence of the
rights of men, whether they be rich or poor, "kindly" tenancies were rigidly
respected wherever there was proper evidence of the preferential right in
which they consisted.
There could not be a better example of this than a
case given in the Book of Lennox. The Crawfords of Jordanhill, near Glasgow,
were a distinguished family in the Sixteenth Century. They had received from
one of the Earls of Lennox the "kindly" Tenancy of a Mill with its adjuncts
in the village of Partick, on the Clyde. Later transactions had placed in
the hands of the Commendator of the Abbey of Paisley, the right of Feuing
lands in the same Barony of Glasgow, but under the restriction that he was
to respect the rights of all "kindly Tenants." In 1587, Thomas Crawford of
Jordanhill seems to have been in some danger of losing his Mill in Partick,
with its adjoining land. James VI. and the Duke of Lennox of that date, were
obliged to interfere, and in the Deed or Warrant to which I refer, they
record the reasons for which they do so. These were twofold. In the first
place, satisfactory evidence had been laid before them "by authentic writ,"
and otherwise, that Thomas Crawford of Jordanhill" was kindly tenant of the
Mill," etc., and that he had been in peaceable possession of it for these
many years bygone by virtue of heritable right and feu granted to him "by
such as had sufficient power for the time to set (let) the same." In the
second place, the King and Duke recount "the good, true, honest, faithful,
and constant service done to us and to our House of Lennox by the said
Thomas, in all time bygone from his youth." Therefore, the Deed declares as
a matter of fact that upon trial or examination, the said Thomas had been
found "to be kindly Tenant of the foresaid Mill and pertinents," and directs
that in future he should hold it "in Feuferme" to his Heirs and Assigns for
ever.
There is, however, a much more remarkable case than this of "kindly"
Tenancy—dating from a much older time, and surviving to the present day.
Long before the great House of Bruce had become allied with the old Royal
Family of Scotland they had been the Lords of Annandale. Not many, miles
from the point where the river Annan falls into the Solway Firth, there is a
little tract of country marked by a curious group of small Lakes. Within the
Parish there are no less than seven of these sheets of water.' Of these the
largest was and is still called Lochmaben. Such situations were naturally
often chosen in the Military Ages for Castles of Defence. So it was in this
case. The mounds and moats which indicate a Castle of great antiquity still
mark the spot where the Lords of Annandale lived before they had risen to
more than Baronial greatness. Another Castle of much more magnificent
proportions also survives, in fragments of massive wall, upon another spot
nearly surrounded by the waters of the largest Lake. Here King Robert loved
to hold Court, both as King and as Lord of Annandale, on his Ancestral
territory. Round this Castle, and by the side of these intertwining Lakes,
there were four of the ancient Farms or Townships of the country, which then
everywhere represented the modes of cultivation and of residence common
among the native population. For some special reason not now known, and at
some time which is equally uncertain— whether before or after the Lords of
Annandale had become Kings of Scotland, one or more of them had granted to
the Tenants and Husbandmen of these Farms some promise or engagement that
they should hold their land on the footing of "kindly Tenants." These "Rentaflers"
were called "the poor Tenants of His Majesty's lands," and "kindly Tenants:"
their duties were called "Rents" and their possessions "Rooms." There was no
written Deed or Charter; but on the other hand there was not only continuous
and unbroken local tradition, but there was an equally unbroken chain of
evidence in the continuous transactions of many generations. Succession to
these holdings had been recognised always by the simple process of writing
the name of the Successor in the Rental Book of the Lord, which entry it was
the custom for the Steward of the Estate or the Constable of the Castle and
Lordship to make without fee or charge. These little holdings were bought
and sold as freely as any other Estate in land. During the course of
centuries, in rude times, and in a Border District when and where it needed
sometimes all the strength of strong men to keep and to hold their own,
these "kindly Tenants" lived on—strong only in the memory of The Bruce.
There were some attempts to oppress them occasionally by the Constables of
the Castle.' But whenever their complaints were brought to the knowledge of
the higher authorities of the Kingdom they were always remedied. On two
recorded occasions there were direct interferences of the Crown—once in the
time of James vi.—once again in the times of Charles II. At a much later
date —in 1726—the Courts of Law were called upon carefully to consider their
titles, and in solemn decisions, not without legal difficulties, these have
always been sustained.' In signal rebuke of the loose and ignorant charge
against the Law, and the Administrators of the Law in Scotland, as if they
had wrongfully construed the rights of property against the poor, the kindly
Tenants of the "Four Towns" of Lochmaben have survived, and still survive
immense changes in surrounding property, for the simple reason that the
evidence of original intention, and of deliberate covenant, although not
resting on written documents, was nevertheless of such a nature as to be
equally conclusive. That evidence clearly distinguished them from ordinary
agricultural Tenants, especially in this, that their rent was from the first
fixed at a rate below that of ordinary value, and had never been on the
footing of a rent variable from time to time, like the rent of ordinary
farms. The ultimate decision of the Courts of Law in Scotland recognised
this tenure as virtually the tenure of a Feu—just as James vi. and the Duke
of Lennox, on another kind of evidence, had recognised the tenure of the
Mill at Partick by Crawford of Jordanhill, as the tenure of a Feu. In virtue
of this decision the kindly Tenants of Lochmaben became Proprietors, and
have ever since been entered as such in the Valuation Roll of the county in
which these lands are situated.
These cases, taken from very different
centuries, and applicable to very different classes of men, show the
principle on which alike the language, and the customs, and the law of
Scotland recognised the position of Tenants who held lands at rents which
were low and fixed, as fundamentally distinct from the position of men who
held land on the ordinary terms of hire. Both were tenures by Covenant; and
both were to be dealt with on evidence of intention. But the nature of the
Covenant in the two cases was wholly different. Where the cheapness of rent
below the ordinary, value was guaranteed permanently and heritably, the
holder of such land was virtually a Feuar, and it was best to recognise his
status as such. In both the instances I have given this was done—in the case
of the man who was already of Proprietary rank, the Laird of Jordanhill, and
in the case of the poor tenants of the Four Towns of Lochmaben, who clearly
belonged at first to the class of Husbandmen, or perhaps of the soldiers and
retainers of the House of Annandale. In other cases of which there appear to
have been many in some centuries, where the grant of land at a low or abated
value was given not heritably but personally to a particular man, his right
was recognised as that of a Liferent, and at his death the Owner of the land
recovered his right to let out his farm on the ordinary, terms of hire. What
these ordinary terms were in principle, and in the universal understanding
and practice, is clear from the mass and variety of transactions in the
nature of Leases which already, as we have seen, had taken written form
nearly a century and a half before the death of King Robert the Bruce. As
regarded agricultural lettings it is clear that the principle and the
practice was that rents should follow real or actual value. Values were
rising with a rising civilisation, and with the progress of improvements
which were made on the strength of undivided Ownership and on the faith of
Covenants founded thereupon. On the other hand, these improvements did not
at that time, when scientific agriculture was unknown, involve the heavy
expenditure of modern Buildings, Drainage, and Fencing. The only draining
known was wide open Ditches—the "Fossae" of many early documents—to cut off
the cultivated land from actual bogs and morasses. The only fencing was made
of rough sticks and branches taken from the nearest brushwood—so light and
flimsy that as we have seen the Lords of Avenel used to break and trample
them down when out with Hounds and Hawks. The only houses were the
traditionary habitations made very much of the same materials—with timber
frames, wattled walls, and an external covering of mud or of some kind of
plaster. Under such conditions the labour of reclaiming and improving land
must have consisted chiefly in digging or trenching, and in taking out the
roots of trees. Very often, in the case-of the poorer class of Tenant, the
oxen for ploughing, and the other cattle, were supplied by the Owner of the
land. Under such conditions the increasing produce of land would speedily
repay the labour spent upon it, and a short term of hire at a rent
proportioned to value at the time of letting, would be an ample inducement
to the cultivating classes to seek the "Tack." This explains the rule laid
down by the Provincial Council of the Church in 1245 that Tacks should not
be granted, and consequently that rents should not be fixed, for a longer
term than five years. This also explains the rapid scale of increase in the
rent at short intervals, which the Tenants agreed to pay within the first
twenty years in the long Scone Lease. These Tenants belonged to the
wealthier class, and they would certainly calculate upon a return suitable
to their condition.
It may be assumed, therefore, upon a combination of
evidence which is conclusive, coming as it does from every direction of the
compass, that the system of Leases as it arose in Scotland, was a system of
definite Covenants for definite terms of years, longer or shorter as special
circumstances might determine in each case, during which the rent was either
absolutely fixed or graduated according to a fixed scale; but at the end of
which the Owner was not only free, but was ordinarily expected to make a new
Covenant, on new conditions such as might bring the rent up to the usual and
average proportion of Rent to total, or gross, Produce. This does not mean
that farms at the end of Leases were let by any process similar to that by
which goods are sold in a modern auction room. That was not the way in which
things were done in those days. The new rent may sometimes have been
settled, as it almost certainly was in the case of the Scone Lease, by the
Owner accepting the voluntary offer of new men of capital like the Hays. But
generally the rent must have been settled not by the highest offer of any
actual or formal competition, but simply and naturally by the amount which
any dozens or scores of men would be eager to give in order to get, or to
renew the Lease.
This is market value in its natural and ordinary sense.
Between this kind of rent and a "fair rent" there was no distinction. In a
manly age men thought that when they bought anything, or hired anything at a
price or rent such as almost any other man would give, they bought or hired
it at a value which was fair. It is remarkable, moreover, that when at a
much later time the loose colloquial expression of a "fair rent" came to be
used for some practical purpose and with some important meaning, and when
the Law was obliged to give to it some definite interpretation, that
interpretation had the effect of identifying a "fair rent" not with a rent
lower than the average, but, on the contrary, with a rent which should not
be lower than that average. This interpretation arose out of the practice of
Entails. The necessity was obvious. When Owners were deprived of the power
of sale, it was absolutely necessary to deprive them also of the power of
alienating under collusive forms. If a man might let his lands at any scale
of rent he liked, however low and however much under the average or market
value, he could of course by accepting large fines on the renewal of Leases
or on the first lettings of land, lower the rental to the point of practical
alienation. To prevent such corrupt practices, and still to preserve the
essential principle of Leases as sanctioned by the Act of 1449, it was
essential to provide that an Entailed Proprietor should not let his farms
below a "fair rent." And again, in order to make this prohibition effectual,
it was absolutely necessary to lay down the principle that by a "fair rent"
was meant a rent fair to all the parties concerned—to the existing Heir in
possession—to his successors in the Estate— to the Tenant, and to the
interests of agriculture, which are never really promoted by the removal of
those incentives to exertion which arise out of the necessity of meeting
obligations. No scale of rent could suit all these conditions except that
representing the value which men of average capital, enterprise, and skill
would be certainly willing to give. In our own day, wherever "the public" is
concerned, the same principle is adopted. Lands are always valued for
purposes of taxation or assessment on the basisof the value at which they
would let one year with another.
A moment's consideration will show that
under such a system as this rents might remain unchanged for
generations—even for centuries, without the slightest inference arising
against these rents being purely a matter of Covenant, or the least
presumption against the right and the power of the Owner to let his lands at
a higher value if he could. The value of everything depends upon
civilisation—not the value of land only, but the value of all its products,
and of all the articles manufactured from these, and most of all, the value
of human labour. But civilisation does not advance everywhere and at all
times. It may, and it often does, stagnate, and for long periods of time it
may, and it often does, go back. The population of particular countries, or
districts of country, may be given up to less improving pursuits than those
of agriculture. Its produce may decline, and a recrudescence of barbarism
may condemn it to chronic poverty and waste. Under such circumstances, of
course, Rent would follow the conditions of Society, of which—like Price in
every other form, and especially like the price of labour—it is only one of
the measures and results. But with the return of peace, and the
recommencement of peaceful industries, the old Covenants would be revived.
Land would regain its natural value, and the same proportion of its total
produce which men are always ready to give for the exclusive possession of
it, would represent a higher rent, because the total produce would itself be
a much larger quantity, and saleable for a much higher price.
But the
universally accepted idea over the whole of Scotland that every form of
possession in land, whether permanent or temporary, rested, and could only
rest upon grant from, or Covenants with, those "who had sufficient .power
and right for the time to grant or to let the same," is an idea which
receives another illustration from another tenure in Scotland which is even
more striking and complete than the tenure by Lease. I refer to the very
peculiar but the very common tenure of older days, which was called "Wadset."
"Wad" or " Wed" is another form of the word " Pledge," and in exact
accordance with the usual meaning of that word, lands let upon "Wad" were
lands lent on Pawn. The Owner, in consideration of a certain sum of money
paid down to him, gave in pawn or in pledge to the Wadsetter certain lands
or farms, under the counter-pledge or Covenant given by the Wadsetter, that
on the same sum in money, or some other sum definitely fixed, being repaid
to him or to his Heirs, he would restore the lands to the former Owner or
his Heirs.
Under this strange tenure large portions of great Estates and
Baronies were often pawned to Wad- setters. Very frequently neither the
Owner nor his Heirs for long periods of time—it might be for
generations—found it convenient to redeem, by repayment of the stipulated
sum. During all that time the Wadsetter was in the enjoyment of the full
rights of Ownership. He might and he often did build valuable houses for the
residence of a Proprietary family—he might and he often did improve the
land, and let it out at increased rents. Yet whenever the original Owner or
his Heirs were enabled to fulfil their part of the bargain the Wad-setter
was bound to fulfil his part of the bargain also—and that bargain was that
the land should return to the Owner, with all its pertinents, according to
the terms of the Covenant. But this, although at variance with popular
sentiments of equity in the present day, was in reality perfectly just, not
only because it was in fulfilment of a deliberate Covenant, but also because
the balance of real advantage as between the two parties, did not by any
means always lie on the side of the Owner who redeemed a valuable Wadset.
The value of the land originally pledged may have been, and generally was,
much more than amounted to fair or ordinary interest upon the sum lent.
Besides this, all the natural or accidental increments of rent which might
arise with the progress of time, from the cessation of wars, or from other
causes, went into the pocket of the Wadsetter, so that by the time of
redemption he might well have been repaid not only the whole of loan, but
very, high or even usurious interest besides. The balance of advantage may
therefore have been very largely on the side of the Wadsetter, because of
his long enjoyment of an enormous return for some small loan borrowed by the
Owner, under the pressure, perhaps, of some great and unforeseen necessity.
It was perfectly equitable that when that necessity had passed away the
"Reverser," as he was called, should re-enter upon his property, and even
its increased value might very well be but a small part of the immense price
he had really paid for a temporary accommodation.
In repeated cases large
Estates, which had been broken up into Wadsets by an extravagant or
unfortunate Owner, have been re-united by some one or more successors who
were frugal in their management, or happy in their alliances and
acquisitions. The Wadsetters often tried to avoid or evade accepting the
redemption money. But both the law and the public sentiment held firmly and
unshakenly to the doctrine that Covenants deliberately made between free men
must be upheld. The Legislature interposed in 1469 to prevent fraudulent
evasions of them. The Courts from time to time were busy in the same work,
and in regulating the rules of warnings of redemption, so as to make all
such Covenants as clear and express as possible, and to make it easy for
both parties to protect themselves against usurious interest on the one
hand, and sudden redemptions on the other. But these objects have always
been aimed at on the principle of reconciling as far as possible unforeseen
and equitable claims with substantial observance of the faith of Covenants.
The tenure of land by Wadset is now extinct, but it has become extinct
mainly from this cause, that whilst some Wadsets were converted into Feus,
or bought up by the Wadsetters, a very large number were extinguished by the
literal fulfilment of the original obligation, by the redemption-money being
paid, and by the wadsetted land being merged in the Estate to which it had
originally belonged.
We have seen in reviewing the Age of Charters how
early they had begun—and how universally they had become established. We
have seen how they forced their own way by the inherent excellence of the
principle on which they were founded—giving form and substance to the long
accepted ideas of men in respect to the actual sources of authority and of
power, whilst at the same time they tended to check the excesses of that
power, and to restrain within the limits of definite law and obligation the
arbitrary exactions of unwritten Feudalism. We have seen how, even in
Ireland, the Celtic Provincial Kings had yielded to their civilising
influence before a single Norman soldier had as yet landed to invade the
Isle of Saints. We have seen how in Scotland even the fierce Lords of the
Isles—the Sons of the wild Somerled of Celtic blood and of Norse
inheritance—had persuaded the lawless Chieftains of the Western Highlands to
accept and to impose the same restrictions on their desolating usages. So
now we have to observe that precisely the same progress was made with all
the corresponding tenures which were subordinate to Charters, and which
rested on the same great principle of defining the rights of men, and of
accustoming them to regulate their dealings with each other on the faith of
Covenants. Accordingly, these subordinate tenures in the form of Leases,
Wadsets, Grants, Warrants, and Agreements of every form and kind spread
rapidly over the whole Kingdom, from the Pentland Firth to the Solway, and
from the Western Isles to the German Ocean. There was no difference betveen
different parts of Scotland in respect to the law, or in respect to the
practices founded upon it, wherever law and order were maintained at all.
Leases and Wadsets—which last tested to the very utmost the principle of
Covenant,—became as common in the heart of the Highlands as they were in the
Lowlands proper, or in the Southern and Border Highlands. In these Border
districts the conditions of Society were long quite as unsettled as in the
Western Mountains or on the Western Coasts. But at all times and in all
places, whenever and wherever peace prevailed, the law of Charters and the
law of Covenants was the law on which men acted and on which men relied—on
the strength of which every step was taken in the path of improvement, and
in the work of civilisation. If in any part of Scotland this system of law
was ever supplanted by a relapse into the old usages of Celtic Feudalism, it
was only in the places where, and in the times when, all law was suspended,
and all improvement stopped, and all civilisation turned back on the way to
Barbarism. This, however, is a subject too interesting and too important to
be treated incidentally. It must form the subject of another chapter.