Not very long ago it
would have been practically impossible to write any accurate or
consecutive account of the taxation and revenue of the ancient kingdom
of Scotland. The earlier chroniclers confined themselves chiefly to
recording the historical events of their time, the lives and deaths of
the kings, their wars and battles, and the events most nearly concerning
the particular districts to which the annalists belonged. The later
historians were too busily occupied in inventing an imaginary and purely
fabulous account of what the history of Scotland ought, in their
opinion, to have been, compounded generally with a total disregard of
what, in point of fact, it actually was, to attend to such prosaic
matters as those relating to the social or economical condition of their
country. But the splendid series of authentic national records which has
been already published and is still being issued by the authorities of
H.M. General Register House, combined with the important contributions
of historical material made by private bodies and individuals, is yearly
adding to our knowledge of the past condition of Scotland, and is
gradually enabling us to correct the erroneous ideas which have too
often and too long hitherto prevailed. The publication of the Acts of
the Parliaments of Scotland has placed a mass of reliable facts of the
highest importance within the reach of the historical student, the value
of which is greatly increased by an elaborate and most valuable index.
Second only in importance to this great national record is the Register
of the Privy Council, which is now in the course of being issued, while
the Rolls of the Exchequer, the Accounts of the Lord High Treasurer, the
Register of the Great Seal, and other publications, will, when
completed, form a mass of evidence available for future historians which
will enable them in many very important points to rewrite the history of
Scotland. And the example thus set has been laudably followed by various
societies and by public spirited individuals in every part of the
country. Perhaps the most important publication after the national
records is the Register of the Convention of Royal Burghs, which for all
matters relating to one very important subject which will shortly engage
our attention, the trade and commerce of early Scotland, is simply
invaluable. But the usefulness of this work is greatly marred by the
want of an index, thereby causing to the student an intolerable and
altogether unnecessary amount of additional labour. It is from the
sources above indicated that we derive our only knowledge of the
revenues of taxation of Scotland in early times. The fiscal history of
Scotland prior to the Union may be conveniently divided into four
periods, each possessing different features. The first is characterized
by a survival of the earlier Celtic imposts, and extends from a very
early period to the reign of David I. The second is marked by feudal
services and casualties, and continues till the return of James I. from
his captivity in England. The third period closes with the accession of
James VI. to the English throne, and exhibits the decay of the feudal
principle of aids. The fourth period comes down to the Union, and shows
the gradual rise of the modern system of taxes.
It will be necessary to
make some preliminary observations. While these characteristics are
sufficiently distinct for purposes of division, it is not to be supposed
that each period is divided from the other by sharply-defined lines of
demarcation. On the contrary, we find in each case the older features
and methods gradually becoming extinct, but sometimes surviving for a
considerable period in remote parts of the country. It is to be
remembered also that a national currency, which now is the familiar
medium both of taxation and revenue, was altogether unknown in Scotland
prior to the reign of David I. who struck silver pennies; and for a long
time afterwards existed only to a very limited amount. Burdens of all
sorts, whether private, local, or public, were at first defrayed either
by services, or labour, or in kind. We can trace the gradual commutation
of these into money payments as the currency extended, and the progress
of civilization rendered it more convenient. It is also to be borne in
mind that many of the duties and obligations now universally undertaken
by the State and paid for by the community by means of taxation were in
early times performed directly by individuals. Thus, the duty of
national defence was a burden imposed on every free man, and was
undertaken by each at his own expense, and it is only in comparatively
later times that we find the State gradually incurring charges for
military stores, occasionally hiring “wageouris” for particular military
services, and so developing into the army estimates of modern days.
Similarly, what is now so familiar to us as the Civil Service
expenditure had equally modest beginnings. The administration of justice
in early times was an unpaid duty which required no national
expenditure. Prior to the reign of David I. the expenses of the country
and of the sovereign were almost entirely defrayed out of the old
prescriptive dues which had descended from the Celtic kingdom, and which
were payable by the community to the King, as well as by tenants to
their chief. These were the Cain, Conveth, Feacht, and Sluaged (which we
have already noticed as agricultural burdens in the first chapter), with
the addition of another called Ich, which, Mr. Skene thinks, is probably
equivalent to loch, payment. These are all enumerated in a grant by Sir
Ewin of Erregeithill to the Bishop of Argyll in 1251 of lands in
Lismore. The Cain provided a large revenue in kind, slowly being
converted into money with smaller payments in silver, gradually getting
larger as the process of commutation extended. The Conveth, which
originated from the right of the Celtic chiefs not only to be obeyed but
to be fed and sustained by the clansmen, appears in the time of Malcolm
IV. (in a charter of Scone) to have been a fixed amount of provisions
paid in kind. It can be identified with the “Waytingaa burden laid on
the thanages, which, in 1292, was assessed in the Exchequer Rolls at 24
cows per annum for two nights’ “waitings” at Forfar, and 13 cows for a
night and a half at Glammis. In Ireland it was called the Coinmedha, and
was the subsistence of the chief or king when out of his own tilled
lands. When systematically due it was called the “Custom of Cuddikie” (Cuid
oidche), and was restricted to four meals, four times in the year, to
the chief and his followers.
“Feacht" and “Shiaged,”
or "expedition and hosting,” covered not only the defence of the
country, but offensive operations against an enemy, and were military
services carried on by the tribesmen at their own charges. Shiaged also
involved attendance at the king’s council. It is termed in the later
records “servitium Scoticanum,” “forinsecum servitium,” and “servitium
in exercitu et auxiliis.” The “Feacht” was the expedition within the
kingdom or territory to repress rebellion or to enforce the law.
The “Ich ” was apparently
a tribute paid at intervals as an acknowledgment of subjection, and
perhaps survived in the “Calpe” or “Cawpe" of more modern times.
In the reign of David I.
we find a very great change introduced. The tenures belonging to the
feudal system, such as military service, ward, and relief, were
gradually supplanting the older tribal system. A national coinage for
the first time enabled a small but ever-increasing proportion of the
revenue to be paid in currency. The establishment of the burghs
encouraged trade and commerce, and the “Leges Burgorzim,” of which a
considerable part belongs to David’s reign, contain probably the
earliest provisions for a regular revenue which we have recorded. Though
no burgh charter is extant belonging to such an early period, the
references constantly made in the later grants of William the Lion to
the privileges possessed by the burghs in the time of his grandfather
show that if particular grants were not in existence some general body
of legislation very favourable to municipal enterprise must have been in
operation. No one can read the eulogium on David by Ailred of Rievaul,
himself the friend and contemporary of the Scottish King, as it is
recorded by Fordun, and confirmed by all that we know, without feeling
that a new era in Scottish history commences with his reign. Society
becomes more civilized, more settled, and therefore more progressive.
“Ancient Gaelic Alban gradually fades into the background,” and of that
historical Scotland of which Edinburgh is the capital, and the “ ruddy
lion ramped in gold ” the emblem, unquestionably David was the creator.
Among the various offices
which can be traced back to his reign is that of the Chamberlain, whose
primary duty was the collection, custody, and disbursement of the
revenue, combined at first with a general supervision over the burghs
from which a very considerable portion of that revenue was derived. The
institution of this office is one of the distinctive features of the
second period indicated above. The national revenue, from many sources
and through various channels, came all eventually to the Treasury, and
from the records, many of which are still extant, we have a tolerably
clear idea of the fiscal system.
The immediate receivers
of the funds were the Sheriffs, who by the time of Alexander III. had
succeeded the Earls as collectors of the revenue; the Ballivi ad extra,
or administrators of some of the Crown lands, or lands temporarily in
possession of the Crown; the Justiciars, the Magistrates, and the
Custumars or receivers of taxes of the burghs.
The sources of income
were either ordinary or extraordinary.
The ordinary sources of
income were (1) the rents of the lands in the possession of the Crown;
(2) the payments due from the Thanages; (3) the casualties of ward,
marriage, relief and non-entry exigible from time to time from the Crown
vassals; (4) fines imposed on misdoers; (5) the escheats, or forfeited
estates of attainted persons; (6) the rents derived from the royal
burghs; (7) compositions payable for letters of gift, remissions, and
legitimations; (8) the Castle wards, or dues exacted from lands in the
immediate vicinity of some of the principal fortresses towards the
expense of upholding them; (9) the duties payable on merchandise, called
the great customs; (10) the profits arising from the coinage of money.
The extraordinary sources
of income were special contributions for particular purposes, and were
at first confined to the occasions recognized by the feudal law, such as
the redemption of the king from captivity, the marriage of his
daughters, etc.
Most of these sources of
income were common to both the periods succeeding the reign of David I.
Taxes in the modern sense of the word were not known till a later
period.
It will be convenient to
indicate shortly the general nature of each of these ordinary sources of
revenue :—
(1) The Crown lands
varied considerably at different periods, but in the time of the
Alexanders were very extensive. They were partly in the actual
occupation of the King (terra dominica or demesne), and cultivated by
his tenants and nativi, and partly held as thanages by vassals who paid
a rent instead of military service. A large portion of this revenue was
at first paid in kind, such as oats, wheat, barley, malt, fodder,
cattle, swine, and poultry. In some districts, such as Forfarshire, part
of it was paid in cheese. When the Exchequer Rolls commenced
considerable sums were paid in money, but the revenue from this source
was very much curtailed by the dilapidation of the Crown lands before
1350.
(2) The thanages were
lands which were granted feudally by charter, not for military services,
but for the payment of an annual sum as “census” or feu-duty. The thanes
held them “in capite” of the Crown, and paid their “reddendo” to the
Sheriffs, who accounted for them to the Exchequer. These were gradually
becoming extinct, and by the close of the reign of Alexander III. had
almost all been converted into ordinary feudal tenures.
(3) The casualties of the
feudal law payable by the vassal to the superior were a very
considerable source of income. They were often gifted by the sovereign
to individuals as rewards for particular services.
(4) Three times in each
year the Justiciar, the supreme judge in criminal and civil cases, held
Circuit Courts at the head burgh of each shire for the administration of
law and the redress of grievances. At the time of the Alexanders there
were three of these officers—the Justiciar of Scotland, of Lothian, and
of Galloway. A large proportion of offences were punished by fines, and
even murder, under the old law of “Cro” or “Wergild,” could be
compounded by the payment of a certain number of cattle, proportioned to
the rank of the victim. The King’s displeasure was often atoned for by a
substantial fine. Thus in 1261 the Earl of Sutherland was fined £20, and
in 1262 the Earl of Caithness paid 50 marks.
(5) Requires no
particular explanation.
(6) The rents derivable
from the royal burghs were, in the first place, an annual payment of
five silver pennies from the holder of each rood of land in a burgh;
secondly, the fines awarded in the Courts of the royal burghs; and
thirdly, the burghal toll or parva custuma. About the beginning of the
fourteenth century the burghs began to rent these petty customs from the
Chamberlain, paying a fixed sum per annum and collecting them themselves
; and some of the burghs, such as Aberdeen, in 1319, and Edinburgh, in
1329, had charters of feu farm from the Crown converting their tacks
into perpetual rights, on payment of a fixed annual reddendo. In 1327
the aggregate revenue derived from this source amounted to £1,133 3s.
4d.
Apart altogether from
their bearing on the national revenue, the accounts of these burgh rents
afford us a very valuable index to the varying states of prosperity of
the different centres of population at different times.
(7) The compositions
payable for letters of gift and other concessions amounted to a
considerable sum in some years, but varied so much that it is impossible
to give an average.
(8) The castle ward
payments were very trifling, and are only important for the principle
recognized in their exaction.
(9) The King’s “great
custom” on merchandise exported must have originated in very early
times, for grants to monasteries of one ship duty free are found in the
reign of David I. It was collected at the ports of export by
“custumars,” who were generally one or two of the leading burgesses
appointed for the purpose and remunerated by fees. It was mainly derived
from three classes of exports —wools, woolfells (or sheepskins), and
hides—and was payable about the time of Robert the Bruce at the rate of
half a mark (6s. 8d. Scots) the sack of twenty-four stones on wool, at a
quarter mark (3s. 4d.) on the hundred of woolfells, and at a mark (13s.
4d.) on the last of hides of twenty dacres, counting at that time
probably ten to the dacre. The revenue derived from this source in 1327
amounted to ,£1,851 14s. 4^d. from the ten principal burghs in the
kingdom.
An important change took
place in 1357. The defeat of the Scots at Durham and the capture of
David II. led to a treaty finally concluded at Berwick, by which England
was to receive 100,000 marks from Scotland in ten yearly instalments,
commencing on the 25th of June, 1358. Among other expedients to raise
this, in those days, enormous sum, the great customs were first trebled,
and afterwards, in 1368, quadrupled; and the revenue from this source
amounted sometimes to over £10,000 in the period between 1370 and 1379.
These increased rates continued long after the ransom had been settled,
for we find them in the succeeding reigns down to a late period.
In the time of James I.
they produced in 1428 £6,912, the highest sum recorded in his reign,
with an annual average of about £5,000. Certain additional customs were
imposed by James I. He taxed the skins of the martin, polecat, otter,
fox, rabbit, and deer. The produce was very trifling, the largest export
being in rabbit skins, and the highest revenue recorded being £3 16s.
8d. in 1431. A further duty was imposed in 1424 of one shilling in the
pound on the exportation of horses, sheep, and cattle, and a small duty
on herrings exported of one penny on every thousand fresh fish sold,
four shillings on each last of 12 barrels barrelled by Scotsmen, six if
by foreigners, and fourpence on every thousand red herrings. A duty of
two shillings in the hundred exported was also laid on "mulones,”
possibly cod. The second Parliament of the same year imposed a new
custom of two shillings in the pound on woollen cloth exported, and
another of two shillings and sixpence in the pound on salmon if bought
by foreigners for exportation. Goods imported from England were also
subjected to a duty of two shillings and sixpence in the pound. The
average amount during the reign of James I. raised from the custom on
woollen cloth was £300 per annum, and from salmon about £115 per annum.
In 1428 a duty appears in the accounts on white salt at the rate of
fivepence for every twelve chalders, but the Act of Parliament imposing
it cannot now be found.
In the reign of James
III. the gross revenue from the wool, woolfells, and hides fell on an
average to less than £2,600. The revenue derived from the salmon and
fish duties during the same period was about £310. Though at first put
on the pound of value it was soon collected on the barrel, 12 of which
made a last of Hamburg measure, and each was to contain 14 gallons. The
custom was raised in 1480 to 4s. per barrel. In 1481 the custom of
Lochfyne herrings amounted to the comparatively large sum of £34, and in
1487 the custom paid on the herrings of the “Lowis” (or Clyde lochs) at
Dumbarton was as much as £379-
The revenue from the
average gross customs in the reign of James III. amounted to about
.£'3,300 annually.
In 1455 the whole customs
of Scotland were annexed inalienably to the Crown.
From a complaint made by
the Comptroller in 1542 it would appear that the total income from this
source then amounted to about ,£5,000.
The later history of the
customs after the accession of James VI. to the English throne must be
dealt with hereafter.
(10) The profits arising
from the coinage do not appear in the Rolls till the reign of David II.
The earlier accounts are, unfortunately, lost. But, in 1358, Adam Thore,
Warden of the Mint, accounted for ^108 5s. 2d. profit to the King
arising from a charge of seven pennies per pound weight of silver. As in
1367 the pound weight of silver was coined into 352 pennies, this was
nearly equal to two per cent. In 1451 the seigniorage had risen to
rather more than three per cent. In 1441 the seigniorage on gold was
16s. from each pound, and in 1525 it had mounted up to 26s. from each
ounce of gold and 20s. from each pound weight of silver minted.
In 1593 the Mint was
farmed out at a weekly rent of one thousand merks, and at the accession
of James VI. to the English throne the seigniorage was fixed at 25s. 5d.
per ounce from the gold coinage and one-twelfth part of the silver
bullion for the silver coinage, including the expense of mintage. In
1683 the Commissioners appointed to report on the Mint affairs
pronounced in favour of a free coinage, which was carried into effect in
1686.
Having reviewed the
ordinary sources of income, we come now to those particular
contributions, which were called for at uncertain intervals and on
special occasions. There is positive evidence in the Cartulary of Scone
that a national aid was asked for in Scotland during the reign of
Malcolm IV. Another is said to have been granted by a National Assembly
in 1174. The first tax of which we have any actual record was imposed in
1190 to assist William the Lion in paying off the 10,000 marks of
sterlings which he agreed to pay to Richard I. of England to obtain the
discharge of the Treaty of Falaise. In 1211 a further aid of 16,000
marks—-10,000 of which were paid by the barons and 6,000 by the burghs—
was granted to the same King. These aids were probably imposed by some
sort of national authority, and in certain cases were assisted by
voluntary contributions. This appears from a deed granted by William the
Lion to the monks of the Cistertian Order, who claimed exemption from
all taxation, but paid their share as a voluntary gift. Evidence exists
in a charter granted to Aberbrothock by Alexander II. that aid had been
called for by him in the beginning of his reign, perhaps on occasion of
the marriage of his sister in 1224. When Alexander III. betrothed his
daughter to Eric of Norway in 1281 he gave her a dowry of fourteen
thousand marks of sterlings, and this sum would in all probability be
raised in the same way. It is certain that during the reigns of the
Alexanders there was a valuation roll or “ extent ” made containing the
actual annual value at that time of a very considerable portion of the
country. All the contributions up to this period were granted under the
then common rule of the feudal system that in certain events the
superior could call on his vassals to grant him special aid. It was not
till after the successful conclusion of the War of Independence that we
find a regular fixed sum granted to the Crown. Upon the 15th July, 1326,
the Earls, Barons, Burgesses, and Free-tenants of Scotland, assembled in
Parliament at Cambuskenneth, granted to Robert Bruce for his life the
tenth penny of their rents, “tam infra burgos et regalitates quam
extra,” according to the valuation made in the reign of Alexander III.,
with the provision that in the cases when the lands had been wasted by
war the owner might apply to the Sheriff for a revaluation. This aid was
given because the Crown lands were so wasted they could not support the
necessary expenses of the King.
David II. was taken
prisoner at the Battle of Durham in 1346, and in 1357 a tax was
appointed to be imposed on all the rents and goods in the kingdom, for
the purpose of paying his ransom of 100,000 marks of sterlings. The
lands were to be taxed on their real value, and various other means were
taken to raise this large sum of money. The financial embarrassment in
which the country was placed by this burden was greatly increased by the
debts and expenses incurred by the King. We get a glimpse of the
comparative wealth of the various classes in Scotland at this period
from the proportions in which the loans were to be gathered. The barons
were to pay one-half, the clergy three-tenths, and the burghs
two-tenths. The Parliament of October, 1370, imposed a special rate of
one shilling in the pound; but, nevertheless, at David’s death, on 22nd
February, 1370-71, there still remained unpaid a balance of 48,000
marks.
When James I. returned
from his captivity in England in 1424 his ransom, decently veiled under
the name of “costage,” was fixed at 60,000 marks of English standard
money, to be paid in six yearly payments of 10,000 marks, but the last
annual instalment was to be repaid as the dowry of the Queen. Of this
large sum the burghs undertook to pay two-fifths, the other two Estates
raising the remaining three-fifths. This affords us some idea of the
comparative wealth of the different classes of population in Scotland at
this period, and shows the progress made by the commercial interest
since the middle of the fourteenth century, when their proportion of
special taxes was only one-fifth, the barons paying one-half and the
clergy three-tenths.
To raise this large sum
special taxation was again imposed by Parliament, besides great
additions to the customs. In every parish and burgh “extentors” were to
be appointed, who, along with the priests, were to value each parish and
town, and enter the rents of the lands, the names of the owners, their
goods and substance in a book, to be presented to the King’s auditors at
Perth. On every pound’s worth of rent and goods in burgh as well as out
the tax was one shilling; every boll of wheat paid two shillings; of
rye, sixteenpence; of oats, sixpence; every cow and her followers of two
years and every ox, six shillings and eightpence; every sheep, one
shilling; and so on. The expenses of the various embassies, such as that
to the Duke of Burgundy in 1471, to France and Spain in 1488, to Denmark
in 1491, and others seem to have been always defrayed by special
taxation. In 1540 we find for the first time a sum imposed on the burghs
for the purpose of furnishing “small artillery” (such as hagbuts and
culverings), the other Estates providing them according to their
valuation. Shortly afterwards a special sum of £16,000 was raised to
assist in sending 1,000 horsemen to the Borders to repress incursions by
“our aulde inymeis.” These were to be engaged for three months, and each
man was to receive four shillings a day. The proportion of the different
Estates in these taxations for national defence are not indicated, but
in 1580, when £40,000 was imposed for defence of the Borders, the Barons
and Freeholders paid two-sixths, the Church three-sixths, and the Burghs
one-sixth.
Occasionally a general
tax was raised for a more local purpose, such as the building of the
bridge at Perth in 1578, the repair of the bridge of Don in 1587, and
the protection of Dumbarton from the inroads of the Leven and the sea in
1607. But the most common cause for these special calls, more especially
after the accession of James VI. to the English throne, was as aids not
only for the contingencies recognized by the old feudal law, but to
defray the Sovereign’s expenses. Thus, in 1625, £400,000 was asked for
to pay the debts of James VI. and the King’s expenses at home and
abroad. In 1630 the same amount was called for, nominally to defray the
expenses of a proposed visit of the King to Scotland ; and special aids
on various other pretexts occur in 1633, 1639, and 1640. No little
dissatisfaction was caused by these exactions, and in 1643 an experiment
was tried of asking for a loan of £800,000, one-sixth of which was to be
advanced by the burghs and the remainder by the clergy, barons, and
freeholders. The nature of the loan will be better understood when it is
remembered that in the following year it was ordained that the names of
those declining to lend were to be publicly read over in Parliament,
their goods escheat, and their persons imprisoned.
During the Commonwealth
matters were, if possible, worse. The Scotch members of Parliament sat
in London, and their voice was little regarded. In 1652 they were
ordered to raise £10,000 a month, and this sum is apparently sterling
money, not Scots currency. The Scotch deputies prayed that Parliament
would allow Scotland to be represented in the Parliament in London in
proportion to its population, but this was refused by the English
Committee, who decided that the number of members should be in
proportion to the money raised from Scotland. On the 10th of March,
1652, the Scotch deputies protested against the heavy burden of taxation
laid upon Scotland, but without any effect. In 1655 there is a return
showing the division of this sum of £10,000 sterling among the various
shires and burghs of the country. From this record we see that the shire
of Ayr had to provide £545 12s. 2d. per month; the shire of Renfrew,
£190 15s. 6d.; the shire of Lanark, £446 8s. gd.; the shire of
Edinburgh, £448 19s. 2d.; the city of Edinburgh, £540; the city of
Perth, £60; and the city of Glasgow, £97 10s.
The money was raised on
all personal as well as real estate, each £20 of personal estate having
to bear the same charge as £1 of valued rent. Tenants, and all persons
by whom annuities, pensions, stipends, or yearly rents or profits were
payable, were to pay the tax and make deductions in reckoning with the
owners and beneficiaries. The commissioners appointed to collect this
tax in each shire or burgh had power to fine, imprison, sequestrate the
estates, and poind and sell the effects of every person refusing to pay.
There was also a power of quartering soldiers upon all persons in
arrear. In 1656 an additional 6d. was assessed upon every £100 Scots of
valued rent to defray the expense of arresting and punishing all
vagrants and vagabonds.
At last General Monk
became satisfied that Scotland could not really pay the sums demanded by
the English Parliament, and he accordingly addressed a letter from
Dalkeith in June, 1657, to Secretary Thurlow, in which he says :—
“I must desire you will
consider this poore country, which truely I can make itt appeare that
one way or other they pay one hundred pounds out of fower for their
assessment: and the warre having soe much exhausted them as itt has done
as by forfeitures and fines wee have much adoe to get itt uppe : and the
soulders that receive itt had almost as well goe without their pay as
gather itt uppe. And unlesse there bee some course taken that they may
come in equality with England itt will goe hard with this people.”
This shows that Scotland
was more heavily taxed in proportion than England, and seems to have had
some effect, for in the same year the proportion payable by Scotland was
reduced to £6,000 per month. But in 1659 it was again raised to £12,000
a month, though probably never paid owing to the King’s restoration in
1660.
Charles II. agreed to
accept the sum of ,£40,000 a year from Scotland, but this sum was paid
entirely by the Customs and Excise. A voluntary supply of £864,000 Scots
was offered by the Scotch Parliament to the King in 1672 for the war
against the States General, which was accepted. A supply was offered by
the estates to James VII. in 1681 amounting to £1,800,000 Scots. In 1696
a supply of £1,440,000 Scots was granted to William II. for the security
of the kingdom, but part of this was raised from the Excise. The last
supply before the Union granted to Queen Anne was in 1706, and amounted
to £577,066 13s. 4d. Scots.
The next great special
source of revenue was the Excise, but this only came into operation at a
comparatively late period. The first notice of it in the Records occurs
in 1644, when Committees were appointed to consider whether money could
be raised for the army by means of Excise. The result was that in the
same year an Act of Parliament was passed imposing Excise duties on ale,
aqua vitae, wine, tobacco, etc. The rates were fourpence on every pint
of ale or small beer; on foreign beer, a shilling; on French wine, is.
4d. per pint; on Spanish wine, 2s. 8d.; on aqua vitae, 2s. 8d.; on every
pound of tobacco, 6s.; on every ox, bull, or cow slaughtered above ,£16
in value, 20s.; if below ,£16 in value, 13s. 4d.; on every ell of silk
stuff imported, from 6s. 8d. to 10s., according to value; on every
beaver hat, 24s.; on every pair of silk stockings, 13s. 4d.; and similar
duties on a long list of like objects. In Royal Burghs the Excise was to
be collected by persons appointed by the Magistrates and Town Councils,
who were allowed to retain 10 per cent, “for public, pious, and
charitable uses within their burghs,” and for payment of the
sub-collectors’ fees and expenses. The elders and deacons of every
landward parish were to collect the Excise in their districts on similar
terms. The original rates were from time to time varied and the articles
added to or altered. In 1647 it was determined to farm the Excise, as
being the most expeditious and easy way of raising the money. Sir
William Dick paid, in 1648, 100,000 merks per annum for the Excise on
wine for three years, and on the expiry of this term in 1651 it was
granted to the Marquis of Argyll and Sir William Dick for five years at
the yearly rent of 140,000 merks per annum, but adding the Excise in
“strong waters.”
We have a very good
account of the fiscal state of Scotland at this period in the report
made by Thomas Tucker in 1656. In May, 1655, Cromwell had appointed a
Council of nine to administer the affairs of Scotland, who inter alia
had full power and authority to collect the duties of Custom and Excise
according to the rates in force in England.
In order to assist at the
settlement of these matters the Lord-Protector and Council of England
sent Mr. Thomas Tucker, then Register to the Commissioners of Excise in
England, into Scotland, and appointed him a Commissioner during his
residence in Scotland. From a letter from one of the Council to
Secretary Thurlow it appears that before the Commonwealth the proceeds
of the Excise on ale, beer, aqua vitae, and tobacco, the most important
articles for excise purposes, had only amounted to about £1,100 sterling
per month, and that the new Council hoped by greater strictness to
double it. Their proceedings excited great discontent, as appears from
the contemporary authors. Nicoll says—“The burdings of the land at this
time (October, 1655) wes verie havie and grevous to be borne;” and
Tucker in his report says the people were very impatient of the Excise
duties to which they were not accustomed, and accounts for it through
“an innate habit of theyr owne to bee crosse, obstinate, clamorous, and
prone to apprehend every action an oppression or injury.”
The first recommendation
made by Tucker was that the Excise should be farmed out to the highest
bidder, but that the term should be at first for four months, afterwards
extended to one year. The result of this was that during the first four
months (19th September, 1655, (January, 1655-56) the amount of Excise
collected amounted to ,£10,471 9s. 10d., of which ,£9,824 was paid by
the tacksmen and ,£647 9s. iod. by collectors directly appointed by the
Commissioners. The greatest difficulties in the collection were in the
Western Highlands. For the counties of Argyll and Bute nobody would bid
anything at all, and only nominal sums for Inverness, Ross, Sutherland,
Cromarty, and Caithness. The Commissioners kept these in their own hands
and sent out two collectors, “gentlemen of those countryes, one of which
went clad after the mode of his countrye with belted playde, trowses,
and brogues,” as Tucker carefully informs us, but only succeeded in
raising ,£27 in Argyll and Bute. In the second tacks for one year from
January, 1655-6, to January, 1656-7, the whole sum raised by the Excise
on ale, beer, and aqua vitae amounted to £35,054 8s. 8d. sterling.
Excise duties were also
charged on salt, but the result was very small.
In 1661 the Excise on
malt was charged at two merks per boll, and in 1693 an additional duty
of 3d. per pint on ale and beer, and 2s. per pint on aqua vitae and
strong waters was imposed. These additional duties were continued by an
Act of 1695. January, 1701, the Excise was farmed for ,£30,000 sterling.
At the period of the
Union the public revenue of Scotland from these various sources was
estimated as follows, in sterling money :—
Excise, per annum
.................................£50,000
Customs, per annum .............................. 50,000
Crown rents and casualties....................... 8,500
Post office and casualties ........................ 2,000
Coinage and casualties ........................... 1,500
Land tax and casualties ........................... 48,000
Total £160,000
Report by Thomas Tucker
Upon the Settlement of the Revenues of Excise and Customs in Scotland
1656 |