In treating this subject
it may be convenient to divide the past into certain periods, and deal
with each separately, showing as far as possible the methods of
cultivation used, the various crops raised, the value received for them,
the relations between owners and occupiers, and the burdens imposed in
the shape of rent (or payments and services in lieu of rent) for the use
of the land. The taxes raised for national and local purposes and laid
on land will be dealt with hereafter.
The divisions proposed
are (1) the Pre-historic period, coming down to about the close of the
seventh century; (2) the Celtic period, coming down to about the close
of the twelfth century; (3) the Early Feudal period, coming down to the
reign of James I.; and (4), lastly, the Later Feudal period, closing
with the union of the two kingdoms in 1707.
It is necessary to bear
in mind concerning the two earlier periods that we are dealing then with
four, at least, distinct races, of different origin, different degrees
of civilization, and having in many cases different customs. Few things
amongst a semicivilized people are so unchangeable as agricultural
customs, and, where the soil and climate permit, they carry to the lands
of their settlement the habits of the land of their origin. We may
expect, for example, to find the Dalriadic Scots following the Hiberno-Scottish
practices, the Norsemen the Norwegian, and so on. Consequently we cannot
safely infer that the same state of progress existed all over the
country. On the contrary, we find in every period that some parts of the
country, peopled by energetic races, were soon far in advance of the
others, and that, even among these, considerable differences in
agricultural progress are found. To give a complete picture of every
part of the country would involve a mass of details which would be out
of place on the present occasion, and for the earlier periods indicated
above would be almost impossible from lack of evidence. All that is
attempted is to give some data which may show points of contrast between
the days we live in and the days gone by, and may stimulate some to
study for themselves the records of the past.
Commencing with the first
of these periods, which extends from an unknown antiquity down to the
seventh century, we are in a position to affirm that at the dawn of
history, when the Roman invasion took place, agriculture was practically
unknown. The earliest historical notices we have of Scotland disclose a
state of society apparently without any knowledge of tillage. Caesar
distinctly says that the inhabitants did not resort to the cultivation
of the soil for food, but were dependent upon their cattle and the flesh
of animals slain in hunting. And so late as the third century Dion
Cassius, according to his abridger, Xifiline, confirmed the fact that
the early Caledonians lived up to that date only by pasturage and the
chase.
How long this condition
of things existed we have no means of ascertaining. Our knowledge of the
Romano-British period, and the three centuries immediately succeeding
it, is so scanty that it is impossible to dogmatize in the absence of
trustworthy evidence. Were conjecture admissible when dealing with
historical matters it might be surmised that the Romans would hardly
have occupied the country so long as they did without introducing
cropping of some kind. But there is no direct evidence of it, so far at
least as Scotland is concerned. “Querns,” the ancient stone handmills,
have been found in the crannogs of Ayrshire, and charred grain (bere and
oats) in the Broch of Dun-beath. But these may have been left by the
last inhabitants, possibly in comparatively recent times. The famous
miracle of S. Ninian about the leeks would show that garden herbs were
known and cultivated in the beginning of the fifth century. But the only
life we now have of the apostle of Galloway was written by Ailred in the
twelfth century, though he professes to write from a very ancient
original, and may have recorded a traditional fact. When we come to
Adamnan’s life of S. Columba we are entitled to believe that agriculture
of a certain sort was practised (at least amongst the Dalriadic Scots)
in the seventh century, if not actually during the saint’s life, a
hundred years earlier. It is related by his biographer that Columba,
when in Iona, having taken from a cottar some bundles of twigs to wattle
a house, sent him in return six measures of barley, which, though not
sown till the 13th of June, were reaped in the beginning of August.
Various other agricultural operations are noticed in the same work.
Ploughing and sowing occur in the 45th chapter of the second book ;
harvest work in the 29th chapter of the first book ; corn-grinding in
the 22nd chapter of the first book; and one of the last earthly deeds of
the saint was to bless the barn of the family of Iona, and two heaps of
winnowed corn which were in it. According to Dr. O’Donovan, cereal crops
were known in Ireland long previous to the introduction of Christianity;
and the Scots of Dalriada may have brought their agricultural knowledge
with them.
Joceline, in his life of
S. Kentigern (or Mungo), of Glasgow, records a miracle which shows that
oxen were used for ploughing ; for he relates how the holy man, not
having any cattle, would have had to let his land lie fallow had not a
stag and a wolf miraculously come out of a wood and ploughed nine acres
for him. But again in this case Joceline wrote centuries after Mungo
slept with the other 654 saints in the cemetery of “Glasghu’; and
probably the correct historical inference is that oxen were used for
agricultural tillage in the twelfth century, when the life was written.
We may, therefore,
reasonably conclude that on the introduction of Christianity into
Scotland agriculture was practised, though we cannot fix the exact
period of its introduction. Neither can we say much regarding the
methods practised nor the results obtained. But it is highly probable
that the system which we find in operation in the immediately succeeding
period existed from a much earlier time, and was the immediate
development of pre-historic rural economy.
During the Celtic period
our knowledge of agricultural methods is still very defective, though we
learn something of the state of land tenure and cultivation from
occasional notices in the earlier chronicles now made accessible, and
from the close analogy which exists between the customs of the various
branches of the Celtic race. We find that at this period, for example,
the social unit both of the Gaelic and Cymric peoples was not the
individual or the family, but the tribe. The territory of the tribe (the
Irish tuath) was held partly in severalty (by the rig and flatlis in
Ireland) and partly in common by the rest of the community. In Celtic
Scotland a somewhat similar state of matters is found. The tribes
occupied their territories in the following manner :— The arable tribe
land was distributed at certain intervals among the free tribesmen. The
pastoral tribe land was held in common. The inheritance land was held by
the headmen as individual property by blood descent. Of these chiefs
there were two sorts, one getting their position by descent, the other
by accumulations of property. They cultivated their estates either by
bond men or by free tenants on a tenure, of which steelbow (or stuht) is
a survival. Strangers in blood to the tribe often joined a sept, and
received a portion from the chief, giving in return their sword-service
and customary dues. Besides the tribe land and the inheritance land,
each clan gave a portion of its territory for the support of the
office-bearers, the Toisech, the Tanist, the File, and the Brehon, and,
after the introduction of Christianity, to the Saggart or priest. The
homestead was composed of a dwelling-house, ox stall, hog sty, a sheep
pen, and a calf-house, and was surrounded by an earthen rampart, and
called usually a Rath. Constant reference to these is made in early
Scottish charters. Thus in the Chartulary of Scone we have a grant to
the Abbey of the Church of Logymahedd, with the Rath “qua est caput
comitatus.” In the Chartulary of Moray we have a notice of the Rath of
Kingussie. In the Chartulary of Arbroath we find the Rath of the
territory of Katerlyn mentioned. This homestead or Rath was the unit of
which the aggregate made up the tribe.
These tuaths or tribes
are found with us both amonff the Northern Piets and the Dalriadac Scots
of the Western Highlands. The notices in the ancient tract quoted by Mr.
Skene, the Amra-Choluim-Chilli, show that in the time of Columba these
tribal settlements existed amongst the Dalriads and the heathen Piets.
For example, we find the land north of the Clyde occupied by three
tribes— the Cinel Gabran, Cinel Angus, and the Cinel Lorn. The Cinel
Gabran occupied Kintyre, Arran, and Bute, and had 560 homesteads, with
20 houses each; the Cinel Angus possessed Isla and Jura, and had 430
homesteads; and the Cinel Lorn peopled the district of that name, and
had 420 homesteads.
We find traces of tribes
also in Galloway. In the charter-room of the Marquess of Ailsa at
Culzean there is a confirmation in 1276 of a charter by Neil of Carrick
to Roland of Carrick, of “ Kenkenol,” or the right of being- head of the
tribe or kin. The tenants of these tribes paid their rent in services or
in kind, for it must be remembered there was no coined money in Scotland
till the time of David I. And of these burdens in lieu of rent there
were at this time four, viz.—Cain, Conveth, Feacht, and Sluaged. The
first two were payments in kind, the others were personal service. We
find these frequently mentioned in the chartularies and in early
charters. Thus King David granted to the Church of Glasgow the tithe of
his “Can” of Strathgrif, Cunningham, Kyle, and Carrick.
Can or Cain was a portion
of the produce of the land, and was rendered in grain from arable farms,
and in stock from pasture land. It was paid by the occupiers of the soil
to the owner in every part of Scotland down to the feudal period, and
long after where feudal tenure did not prevail.
Conveth was founded on
the original right which the leaders of the Celtic tribe had to be
supported by their followers, and it finally became a fixed contribution
on each plough-gate of land. In the Chartu-lary of Scone we find a grant
from Malcolm IV. to the abbey at the Feast of All Saints, for their
conveth, of i cow and 2 pigs, some meal and oats, 10 hens, 200 eggs, 10
bundles of candles, 4 lb. of soap, and 20 half-meales of cheese. In the
Western Highlands this rent was called the “ Cuddicke,” and is mentioned
in the Western Islands late on in the fifteenth century, and is found
later still in Atholl. It is sometimes also called “ Conyouunder which
form it occurs in a contract between the Bishop of the Isles and
Lauchlan M‘Lean of Dowart in 1580. A somewhat similar rent, called
Sorrynwas of old exacted in Galloway.
The “Feacht” and
“Sluaged" were obligations of personal service to follow the head of the
tribe in expeditions and wars, and in Scotland were laid on the davoch
of land. These ancient Celtic obligations appear in later times to be
what is called in old charters “Scottish service,” or “expedition and
hosting.”
Such were the obligations
of the occupiers and tillers of the ground from the earliest dawn of
authentic record down to the close of the Celtic period in the eleventh
century.
Coming now to the earlier
feudal period, we glean our chief information as to the state of rural
economy mostly from the chartularies and registers of the great
religious houses. From these we can gather a tolerably exact account of
the state of agriculture from the eleventh to the close of the
thirteenth centuries. During this period we cannot trace any legal
enactments, but there is no doubt that the force of custom, in itself
almost stronger in rude nations than that of law, existed, and
stereotyped what men were to do with regard to the cultivation of the
soil.
It is hardly necessary to
say that the monks were the great promoters and encouragers of
agriculture. One of the earliest sources of knowledge we have is a
rental of the possessions of the Abbey of Kelso, drawn up in 1290.
From it we find that in
each principal district there was a “grange,” or abbey homestead. It was
usually under the charge of a lay brother of the convent, or sometimes
of one of the monks, and included the store-house for the implements,
the byres for cattle, the home of the “carles', and the granary of the
domain, or “mains." The carles (nativi, or serfs) were really bondmen,
who belonged to the land and went with it. Outside the “ grange ” dwelt
the “cottarii” or cottars, occupying a hamlet, or “town,” with from one
to nine acres each of land, for which they paid a money rent and certain
services. Then came the “husbandi,” or “malars or farmers, renting a “
husbandlandThis husband-land was generally two oxgates of land, each 13
acres, “where plough and scythe could gang.” Four husbandmen occupied
together a plough-gate, equal to 104 acres, and had a common plough to
which each contributed two oxen. These were neighbours, and strict rules
of good fellowship were laid down, and, when necessary, enforced by the
“birley men ” chosen by themselves.
As early as 1185 there
were enclosed fields for cultivation, for in that year Robert Avenel
gave to the monks of Melrose certain lands in Upper Esk-dale, and the
privilege of hunting and hawking without prejudice to the enclosures.
When we come to consider
the return from land during this period we have to deal with the
important factor of money payments as well as services and payments in
kind. And we also find a very great advance in civilization and in the
methods of agriculture. The monastic chartularies and rentals give some
idea of the burdens then imposed on tenants. One example may serve as a
sort of guide. On the barony of Bolden the monks had twenty-eight
husbandlands. Each paid eighty sterlings or silver pennies annually as
silver rent, and the following services besides, viz., the whole family
gave four days’ reaping in harvest, one day carrying peats, a man and a
horse to and from Berwick once a year, an acre and a half’s ploughing
and one day’s harrowing, a man at sheep-washing and one at
sheep-shearing, and one day’s work with a waggon at harvest time.
Besides these, each farmer had to take the abbot’s wool to the abbey and
pay a reek-hen at Christmas. In addition to the 28 principal farmers
there were 36 cottars, 1 miller, and 4 brewers. Each of the cottages had
half an acre of land. The cottars rendered certain services and paid in
whole 668 sterlings. The mill rented for 8 merks, and the four
brew-houses paid 120 sterlings yearly.
We find that they
produced oats, wheat, barley, pease, and beans. There is very little
mention of rye. Lint paid teind in the reign of William the Lion in
Moray. Oats were the main crop, furnishing both meal and malt. Much
larger quantities were grown than might be expected. In 1300 the cavalry
of Edward of England, returning from Galloway, when near Dornoch, in
Dumfriesshire, passed through the growing crops of a proprietor there,
who claimed damages for 80 acres of oats injured. The claim was
admitted, and a sum of 5,760 sterlings paid him as damages, or at the
rate of 72 per acre. Barley malt is very rare, and high in price. In
1300 oats and oat malt were 42 sterlings a quarter, and barley malt 52;
wheat was 84 sterlings the quarter, beans 60 sterlings, and pease 33
sterlings. The usual price for a chalder of oats was a merk (160
sterlings) though sometimes it rose as high as 240 sterlings ; while
that of barley was a merk, though sometimes it fell to 120 sterlings.
Cheese was made in
considerable quantities at an early period. Malcolm IV. granted to the
monks of Melrose a place at Cumbesley to build a dairy for 100 cows.
We need only refer to one
more authority of this sort for the same period. In the venerable
Chartulary of Melrose there are many most interesting-incidental notices
throwing light on rural affairs down to the death of Alexander III. We
find strict rules laid down for the protection of growing corn and hay
meadows. We find wheat cultivated, and wheaten bread used on holidays.
Roads—in some cases at least suitable for wheel vehicles—as appears from
the penalty for trespassing on private roads, being fixed at a penny for
a four-wheeled and a halfpenny for a two-wheeled waggon—were frequent,
and wheeled conveyances in common use. Mills driven by wind or water
were used for grinding corn, though the old “quern” still held its own
in some districts.
With regard to stock, it
appears from a record in the same chartulary that the monks in 1247
bought from Patrick of Dunbar his stud of horses and brood mares for
8,000 silver pennies, a very large sum in those days. Of sheep the abbey
had immense flocks. Three flocks of wedders, of 500 each, were pastured
near Hart’s-head in Haddington. From Roland of Galloway they had
pasturage for 700 ewes with their followers of two years, for 49 cows
similarly attended, a bull, 40 oxen, 8 horses, and 4 swine with their
followers for three years. In Wedale they grazed 7 score cattle and 500
sheep, and on Primside 400 sheep.
Minute and careful
arrangements are laid down for the folds and fanks, the shepherds,
separation of pastures, removal of stock at various times of the year,
etc. The shepherds in some cases had movable lodges with them.
In this period we find
for the first time positive laws relating to the land and agriculture.
In the year 1214 bondsmen were to begin to plough and sow 15 days before
the Feast of the Purification. And, to encourage agriculture, Alexander
II. in the same Parliament ordered every person who possessed more than
four cows to rent land and plough it with the cattle; and those who had
fewer cattle were to till it by hand labour, under certain pains and
penalties.
And in a fragment of
uncertain date it is laid down that if a tenant puts “gule” (a noxious
weed not unknown at the present day) in the land he is to be punished as
if he had led an enemy into the country—that is apparently with death.
Should it be owing to the carelessness of a bondager, he shall pay a
sheep for every plant of it, and clean the land besides. |